Supreme Court of California Justia
Docket No. S212072
Cal. Bldg. Industry Assn. v. City of San Jose

Filed 6/15/15



IN THE SUPREME COURT OF CALIFORNIA



CALIFORNIA BUILDING INDUSTRY )
ASSOCIATION,

Plaintiff and Respondent,

S212072

v.

Ct.App. 6 H038563

CITY OF SAN JOSE,

Santa Clara County

Defendant and Appellant;

Super. Ct. No. CV167289

)
AFFORDABLE HOUSING NETWORK )
OF SANTA CLARA COUNTY et al., )
)


Interveners and Appellants. )

_________________________________________)


Health and Safety Code section 50003, subdivision (a), currently provides:

―The Legislature finds and declares that . . . there exists within the urban and rural

areas of the state a serious shortage of decent, safe, and sanitary housing which

persons and families of low or moderate income . . . can afford. This situation

creates an absolute present and future shortage of supply in relation to demand . . .

and also creates inflation in the cost of housing, by reason of its scarcity, which

tends to decrease the relative affordability of the state‘s housing supply for all its

residents.‖

This statutory language was first enacted by the Legislature over 35 years

ago, in the late 1970s. (Stats. 1975, 1st Ex. Sess., ch. 1, § 7, pp. 3859-3861,

adding Health & Saf. Code, former § 41003; Stats. 1979, ch. 97, § 2, p. 225,



amending Health & Saf. Code, § 50003.) It will come as no surprise to anyone

familiar with California‘s current housing market that the significant problems

arising from a scarcity of affordable housing have not been solved over the past

three decades. Rather, these problems have become more severe and have reached

what might be described as epic proportions in many of the state‘s localities. All

parties in this proceeding agree that the lack of affordable housing is a very

significant problem in this state.

As one means of addressing the lack of a sufficient number of housing units

that are affordable to low and moderate income households, more than 170

California municipalities have adopted what are commonly referred to as

―inclusionary zoning‖ or ―inclusionary housing‖ programs. (Non-Profit Housing

Association of Northern California, Affordable by Choice: Trends in California

Inclusionary Housing Programs (2007) p. 3 (hereafter NPH Affordable by

Choice).) As a 2013 publication of the United States Department of Housing and

Urban Development (HUD) explains, inclusionary zoning or housing programs

―require or encourage developers to set aside a certain percentage of housing units

in new or rehabilitated projects for low- and moderate-income residents. This

integration of affordable units into market-rate projects creates opportunities for

households with diverse socioeconomic backgrounds to live in the same

developments and have access to [the] same types of community services and

amenities . . . .‖ (U.S. Dept. of Housing and Urban Development, Inclusionary

Zoning and Mixed-Income Communities (Spring 2013) Evidence Matters, p. 1,

fn. omitted (hereafter 2013 HUD Inclusionary Zoning)

2

<http://www.huduser.org/portal/periodicals/em/spring13/highlight3.html> [as of

June 15, 2015].)1

In 2010, after considerable study and outreach to all segments of the

community, the City of San Jose (hereafter sometimes referred to as the city or

San Jose) enacted an inclusionary housing ordinance that, among other features,

requires all new residential development projects of 20 or more units to sell at

least 15 percent of the for-sale units at a price that is affordable to low or moderate

income households. (The ordinance is described in greater detail in pt. II., post.)

Very shortly after the ordinance was enacted and before it took effect,

plaintiff California Building Industry Association (CBIA) filed this lawsuit in

superior court, maintaining that the ordinance was invalid on its face on the

ground that the city, in enacting the ordinance, failed to provide a sufficient

evidentiary basis ―to demonstrate a reasonable relationship between any adverse

public impacts or needs for additional subsidized housing units in the City

ostensibly caused by or reasonably attributed to the development of new


1

The 2013 HUD article further explains that inclusionary zoning or housing

programs ―vary in their structure; they can be mandatory or voluntary and have
different set-aside requirements, affordability levels, and control periods. Most
[inclusionary zoning] programs offer developers incentives such as density
bonuses, expedited approval, and fee waivers to offset some of the costs associated
with providing the affordable units. Many programs also include developer opt-
outs or alternatives, such as requiring developers to pay fees or donate land in lieu
of building affordable units or providing the units offsite. Studies show that
mandatory programs produce more affordable housing than voluntary programs,
and developer opt-outs can reduce opportunities for creating mixed-income
housing. At the same time, [inclusionary zoning‘s] reliance on the private sector
means that its effectiveness also depends on the strength of a locality‘s housing
market, and researchers acknowledge that a certain degree of flexibility is essential
to ensuring the success of [inclusionary zoning] programs.‖ (2013 HUD
Inclusionary Zoning
, supra, at p. 1, fns. omitted.)

3

residential developments of 20 units or more and the new affordable housing

exactions and conditions imposed on residential development by the Ordinance.‖

The complaint maintained that under the ―controlling state and federal

constitutional standards governing such exactions and conditions of development

approval, and the requirements applicable to such housing exactions as set forth in

San Remo Hotel v. City and County of San Francisco (2002) 27 Cal.4th 643, and

Building Industry Assn. of Central California v. City of Patterson (2009) 171

Cal.App.4th 886‖ the conditions imposed by the city‘s inclusionary housing

ordinance would be valid only if the city produced evidence demonstrating that the

requirements were reasonably related to the adverse impact on the city‘s

affordable housing problem that was caused by or attributable to the proposed

new developments that are subject to the ordinance’s requirements, and that the

materials relied on by the city in enacting the ordinance did not demonstrate such a

relationship. Although the complaint did not explicitly spell out the specific

nature of its constitutional claim, CBIA has subsequently clarified that its

challenge rests on ―the unconstitutional conditions doctrine, as applied to

development exactions‖ under the takings clauses (or, as they are sometimes

denominated, the just compensation clauses) of the United States and California

Constitutions. CBIA‘s challenge is based on the premise that the conditions

imposed by the San Jose ordinance constitute ―exactions‖ for purposes of that

doctrine. The superior court agreed with CBIA‘s contention and issued a

judgment enjoining the city from enforcing the challenged ordinance.

The Court of Appeal reversed the superior court judgment, concluding that

the superior court had erred (1) in finding that the San Jose ordinance requires a

developer to dedicate property to the public within the meaning of the takings

clause, and (2) in interpreting the controlling constitutional principles and the

decision in San Remo Hotel v. City and County of San Francisco, supra, 27

4

Cal.4th 643 (San Remo Hotel), as limiting the conditions that may be imposed by

such an ordinance to only those conditions that are reasonably related to the

adverse impact the development projects that are subject to the ordinance

themselves impose on the city‘s affordable housing problem. Distinguishing the

prior appellate court decision in Building Industry Assn. of Central California v.

City of Patterson, supra, 171 Cal.App.4th 886 (City of Patterson), the Court of

Appeal held that the appropriate legal standard by which the validity of the

ordinance is to be judged is the ordinary standard that past California decisions

have uniformly applied in evaluating claims that an ordinance regulating the use of

land exceeds a municipality‘s police power authority, namely, whether the

ordinance bears a real and substantial relationship to a legitimate public interest.

The Court of Appeal concluded that the matter should be remanded to the trial

court for application of this traditional standard.

CBIA sought review of the Court of Appeal decision in this court,

maintaining that the appellate court‘s decision conflicts with the prior Court of

Appeal decision in City of Patterson, supra, 171 Cal.App.4th 886, and that City of

Patterson was correctly decided and should control here. We granted review to

determine the soundness of the Court of Appeal‘s ruling in this case.

For the reasons discussed below, we conclude that the Court of Appeal

decision in the present case should be upheld. As explained hereafter, contrary to

CBIA‘s contention, the conditions that the San Jose ordinance imposes upon

future developments do not impose ―exactions‖ upon the developers‘ property so

as to bring into play the unconstitutional conditions doctrine under the takings

clause of the federal or state Constitution. Furthermore, unlike the condition that

was at issue in San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, and to which the passage

in that opinion upon which CBIA relies was addressed — namely, an in lieu

monetary fee that is imposed to mitigate a particular adverse effect of the

5

development proposal under consideration — the conditions imposed by the San

Jose ordinance at issue here do not require a developer to pay a monetary fee but

rather place a limit on the way a developer may use its property. In addition, the

conditions are intended not only to mitigate the effect that the covered

development projects will have on the city‘s affordable housing problem but also

to serve the distinct, but nonetheless constitutionally legitimate, purposes of

(1) increasing the number of affordable housing units in the city in recognition of

the insufficient number of existing affordable housing units in relation to the city‘s

current and future needs, and (2) assuring that new affordable housing units that

are constructed are distributed throughout the city as part of mixed-income

developments in order to obtain the benefits that flow from economically diverse

communities and avoid the problems that have historically been associated with

isolated low income housing. Properly understood, the passage in San Remo Hotel

upon which CBIA relies does not apply to the conditions imposed by San Jose‘s

inclusionary housing ordinance.

Accordingly, we conclude that the judgment of the Court of Appeal in this

case should be affirmed.

I. Statutory background

We begin with a brief summary of the California statutes that form the

background to the San Jose ordinance challenged in this case.

Nearly 50 years ago, the California Legislature enacted a broad measure

requiring all counties and cities in California to ―adopt a comprehensive, long-

term general plan for the physical development of the county or city.‖ (Gov.

Code, § 65300 et seq., enacted by Stats. 1965, ch. 1880, § 5, pp. 4334, 4336,

operative Jan. 1, 1967.) Each municipality‘s general plan is to contain a variety of

mandatory and optional elements, including a mandatory housing element

consisting of standards and plans for housing sites in the municipality that ―shall

6

endeavor to make adequate provision for the housing needs of all economic

segments of the community.‖ (Gov. Code, former § 65302, subd. (c), as amended

by Stats. 1967, ch. 1658, § 1, p. 4033; see now Gov. Code, § 65580.)

A little more than a decade later, in 1980, declaring (1) that ―[t]he

availability of housing is of vital statewide importance,‖ (2) that ―the early

attainment of decent housing and a suitable living environment for every

Californian . . . is a priority of the highest order,‖ (3) that ―[t]he early attainment of

this goal requires the cooperative participation of government and the private

sector in an effort to expand housing opportunities and accommodate the housing

needs of Californians of all economic levels,‖ and (4) that ―[l]ocal and state

governments have a responsibility to use the powers vested in them to facilitate the

improvement and development of housing to make adequate provision for the

housing needs of all economic segments of the community‖ (Gov. Code, § 65580,

subds. (a), (b), (d), italics added), the Legislature enacted a separate,

comprehensive statutory scheme that substantially strengthened the requirements

of the housing element component of local general plans. (Gov. Code, §§ 65580-

65589, enacted by Stats. 1980, ch. 1143, § 3, pp. 3697-3703.) The 1980

legislation — commonly referred to as the ―Housing Element Law‖ (see, e.g.,

Fonseca v. City of Gilroy (2007) 148 Cal.App.4th 1174, 1179) — sets forth in

considerable detail a municipality‘s obligations to analyze and quantify the

locality‘s existing and projected housing needs for all income levels, including the

locality‘s share of the regional housing need as determined by the applicable

regional ― ‗[c]ouncil of governments‘ ‖ (Gov. Code, § 65582, subd. (b)), and to

adopt and to submit to the California Department of Housing and Community

Development a multiyear schedule of actions the local government is undertaking

to meet these needs. (Id., §§ 65583-65588.) In particular, the legislation requires

a municipality, ―[i]n order to make adequate provision for the housing needs of all

7

economic segments of the community, . . . [to] [¶] [i]dentify actions that will be

taken to make sites available during the planning period . . . with appropriate

zoning and development standards and with services and facilities to

accommodate that portion of the city‘s or county‘s share of the regional housing

need for each income level‖ (Gov. Code, § 65583, subd. (c)(1)) and to ―[a]ssist in

the development of adequate housing to meet the needs of extremely low, very

low, low-, and moderate-income households.‖ (Id., subd. (c)(2).)

In addition to adopting the Housing Element Law, the Legislature has

enacted a variety of other statutes to facilitate and encourage the provision of

affordable housing, for example, prohibiting local zoning and other restrictions

that preclude the construction of affordable housing units (see, e.g., Gov. Code,

§§ 65913.1 [least cost zoning law], 65589.5 [Housing Accountability Act]), and

requiring local governments to provide incentives, such as density bonuses, to

developers who voluntarily include affordable housing in their proposed

development projects. (Gov. Code, § 65915.) Furthermore, with respect to two

geographic categories — redevelopment areas and the coastal zone — the

Legislature has enacted statutes explicitly directing that new residential

development within such areas include affordable housing units. (See Health &

Saf. Code, § 33413, subd. (b)(1), (2)(A)(i) [redevelopment areas]; Gov. Code,

§ 65590, subd. (d) [coastal zone].)

Although to date the California Legislature has not adopted a statewide

statute that requires every municipality to adopt a mandatory inclusionary housing

ordinance if needed to meet the municipality‘s obligations under the Housing

Element Law, in recent decades more than 170 California cities and counties have

adopted such inclusionary housing ordinances in an effort to meet such

obligations. (See generally NPH Affordable by Choice, supra, pp. 3, 40 [listing

cities and counties with inclusionary policies as of 2006]; Nat. Housing

8

Conference, Inclusionary Zoning: The California Experience (Feb. 2004) NHC

Affordable Housing Policy Review, vol. 3, issue 1; Calavita et al., Inclusionary

Housing in California: The Experience of Two Decades (1998) 64 J. Amer.

Planning Assn. 150, 158-164.) The provisions and legislative history of the

affordable housing statutes make it clear that the California Legislature is

unquestionably aware of these numerous local mandatory inclusionary housing

ordinances and that the existing state legislation is neither inconsistent with nor

intended to preempt these local measures.2


II. Background and description of challenged San Jose inclusionary

housing ordinance

It is within the context of the foregoing statutory framework that San Jose

began considering the need and desirability of adopting an inclusionary housing


2

For example, Government Code section 65589.5, subdivision (f)(1), a

provision of the Housing Accountability Act, provides in this regard, in part:
―Nothing in this section shall be construed to prohibit a local agency from
requiring the development project to comply with objective, quantifiable, written
development standards, conditions, and policies appropriate to, and consistent
with, meeting the jurisdiction‘s share of the regional housing need pursuant to
Section 65584.‖ Similarly, although the legislative history of the density bonus
law, Government Code section 65915, discloses a disagreement among supporters
of the law with regard to how that statute would apply to developers subject to a
local mandatory inclusionary housing ordinance, that history makes clear that
there was agreement that the density bonus law ―does not preempt the ability [of]
local ordinances to require the inclusion of affordable (low, very low, or moderate-
income) units within a housing development.‖ (Sen. Hollingsworth, letter to Sen.
Pereira (Aug. 25, 2005) ___ Sen. J. (2005-2006 Reg. Sess.) pp. 2293-2294
[legislative intent of Sen. Bill No. 435 (2005-2006 Reg. Sess.) and Sen. Bill No.
1818 (2003-2004 Reg. Sess.)], reprinted at Historical and Statutory Notes, 36D
West‘s Ann. Gov. Code (2009 ed.) foll. § 65915, pp. 233-234; see
Assemblymember Mullin, letter (Sept. 8, 2005) 3 Assem. J. (2005-2006 Reg.
Sess.) pp. 3670-3671 [same], reprinted at Historical and Statutory Notes, 36D
West‘s Ann. Gov. Code, supra, at p. 234.)

9

ordinance. As noted, the statewide Housing Element Law places responsibility

upon a city to use its powers to facilitate the development of housing that makes

adequate provision for all economic segments of the community, in particular

extremely low, very low, lower and moderate income households, including the

city‘s allocation of the regional housing need as determined by the applicable

regional council of governments. (Gov. Code, §§ 65580, subd. (d), 65583,

65584.)3

In December 2008, the Association of Bay Area Governments (ABAG), the

regional council of governments within whose jurisdiction the City of San Jose

falls (see Gov. Code, § 65588, subd. (e)(1)(B)), calculated San Jose‘s share of the

regional need for new housing over the 2007-2014 planning period as

approximately 34,700 units, of which approximately 19,300 units — or about 60

percent of the new housing units in San Jose — would be needed to house

moderate, low, very low, and extremely low income households. As of February

2009, however, San Jose had met only a small percentage of its regional need

allocation for moderate or lower income households (6 percent of the need for

moderate income households, 2 percent for lower income households, 16 percent

for very low income households, and 13 percent for extremely low income

households, respectively).


3

California statutes generally define the various low and moderate income

levels by reference to the levels set by federal law, but in the absence of applicable
federal standards, extremely low income households are defined as those earning
no more than 30 percent of the area median income (adjusted for family size)
(Health & Saf. Code, § 50106); very low income households are defined as those
earning no more than 50 percent of the area median income (id., § 50105); lower
income households are defined as those earning no more than 80 percent of the
area median income (id., § 50079.5); and moderate income households are defined
as those earning less than 120 percent of area median income. (Id., § 50093.)

10

Prior to the adoption of the challenged citywide ordinance in 2010, San

Jose‘s experience with a mandatory inclusionary housing policy was limited to

residential development projects that were undertaken within the redevelopment

areas of the city. (At that time, redevelopment areas comprised almost 20 percent

of the city‘s territory and included one-third of the city‘s population.) As noted,

redevelopment areas were one of the two types of locations within which the

Legislature had directed that any new residential development must include some

affordable housing units. Under the applicable statute, at least 15 percent of all

new or substantially rehabilitated dwelling units in a redevelopment project

undertaken by a public or private entity other than the redevelopment agency were

required to be made available at an affordable housing cost and to be occupied by

persons and families of low or moderate income. (Health & Saf. Code, § 33413,

subd. (b)(2)(A)(i).)4 Between 1999 and 2009, more than 10,000 affordable

housing units had been built in the redevelopment areas of San Jose under the

city‘s redevelopment inclusionary housing policy.

In part as a result of this experience with a mandatory inclusionary housing

requirement in its redevelopment areas, the city began considering the feasibility

of adopting a citywide inclusionary housing policy. Out of concern for the

potential economic impact of such a citywide requirement on developers,

however, the city retained a private consulting firm to conduct an economic

feasibility study of a citywide inclusionary housing policy. The very extensive

300-page study, prepared by the consulting firm with input from developers,


4

The statute also requires that when new (or substantially rehabilitated)

dwelling units are developed in a redevelopment project by the redevelopment
agency itself, at least 30 percent of the units must be affordable to low or moderate
income families. (Health & Saf. Code, § 33413, subd. (b)(1).)

11

affordable housing advocates, community organizations and others, concluded that

inclusionary housing could be economically feasible with certain developer

incentives and under improved economic conditions.

After reviewing the study, the city council directed city staff to obtain

further input from affected stakeholders and the community generally and then to

bring a draft policy to the council for its consideration. Between June and

December 2008, officials at the city housing department held more than

50 meetings with community members, developer and labor associations,

affordable housing advocates and community organizations, and presented a draft

policy to the council. In December 2008, after discussion, the city council

directed staff to draft an inclusionary housing ordinance that would meet specified

requirements agreed upon by the council. A draft ordinance was written and

released for public review in July 2009, and between July and October 2009 nine

public meetings were held throughout the city to discuss the draft ordinance. On

January 26, 2010, the city council adopted the citywide inclusionary housing

ordinance at issue in this case. (San Jose Ordinance No. 28689, amending San

Jose Mun. Code, tit. 5 to add new ch. 5.08 adopting a ―citywide inclusionary

housing program‖; San Jose Mun. Code, §§ 5.08.010-5.08.730.)5

We summarize the principal provisions of the lengthy ordinance, which

runs 57 pages.

The ordinance begins with a list of findings and declarations, detailing the

steady increase in the cost of housing in San Jose generally and the substantial


5

Hereafter, we shall cite sections of the ordinance using the following

format, e.g., S.J.M.C. § 5.08.010. The ordinance is available online at
<https://www.municode.com/library/ca/san_jose/codes/code_of_ordinances> [as
of June 15, 2015.

12

need for affordable housing for extremely low, very low, lower, and moderate

income households to meet the city‘s regional housing needs allocation as

determined by ABAG. The findings note that ―[r]equiring affordable units within

each development is consistent with the community‘s housing element goals of

protecting the public welfare by fostering an adequate supply of housing for

persons at all economic levels and maintaining both economic diversity and

geographically dispersed affordable housing.‖ (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.010 F.) The

findings further observe that requiring builders of new market rate housing to

provide some housing affordable to low and moderate income families ―is also

reasonably related to the impacts of their projects, because: [

1. Rising land

prices have been a key factor in preventing development of new affordable

housing. New market-rate housing uses available land and drives up the price of

remaining land. New development without affordable units reduces the amount of

land development opportunities available for the construction of affordable

housing. [¶] 2. New residents of market-rate housing place demands on services

provided by both public and private sectors, creating a demand for new

employees. Some of these public and private sector employees needed to meet the

needs of the new residents earn incomes only adequate to pay for affordable

housing. Because affordable housing is in short supply in the city, such

employees may be forced to live in less than adequate housing within the city, pay

a disproportionate share of their incomes to live in adequate housing in the city, or

commute ever increasing distances to their jobs from housing located outside the

city. These circumstances harm the city‘s ability to attain employment and

housing goals articulated in the city‘s general plan and place strains on the city‘s

ability to accept and service new market-rate housing development.‖ (Ibid.)

The next section, setting forth the purposes of the ordinance, explains that a

principal purpose is to enhance the public welfare by establishing policies

13

requiring the development of housing affordable to low and moderate income

households in order to meet the city‘s regional share of housing needs and

implement the goals and objectives of the city‘s general plan and housing element.

A further purpose is to provide for the residential integration of low and moderate

income households with households of market rate neighborhoods and to disperse

inclusionary units throughout the city where new residential development occurs.

In addition, the ordinance is intended to alleviate the impacts that would result

from the use of available residential land solely for the benefit of households that

are able to afford market rate housing and to mitigate the service burden imposed

by households in new market rate residential developments by making additional

affordable housing available for service employees. Finally, the ordinance

provides residential developers with a menu of options from which to select

alternatives to the construction of inclusionary units on the same site as market

rate residential developments. (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.020.)

The substantive provisions of the ordinance follow. The requirements

contained in the ordinance apply to all residential developments within the city

that create 20 or more new, additional, or modified dwelling units. (S.J.M.C.

§ 5.08.250 A.) With regard to such developments, the ordinance‘s basic

inclusionary housing requirement specifies that 15 percent of the proposed on-site

for-sale units in the development shall be made available at an ―affordable housing

cost‖ to households earning no more than 120 percent of the area median income

for Santa Clara County adjusted for household size. (S.J.M.C. §§ 5.08.400 A.1.,

5.08.130.) The ordinance generally defines affordable housing cost by reference

to the definition set forth in Health and Safety Code section 50052.5 (S.J.M.C.

§ 5.08.105), which in turn defines affordable housing cost as 30 percent of the area

median income of the relevant income group (i.e. extremely low, very low, lower

14

and moderate income). (Health & Saf. Code, § 50052.5, subd. (b)(1), (2), (3),

(4).)6

As an alternative to providing the required number of for-sale inclusionary

units on the same site as the market rate units, the ordinance affords a developer a

number of compliance options. At the same time, as an apparent incentive to

encourage developers to choose to provide on-site inclusionary units, the


6

In addition to requiring 15 percent of for-sale units to be made available at

an affordable housing cost, with respect to rental residential development the
ordinance requires 9 percent of the units to be made available for rent at an
affordable housing cost to moderate income households, and 6 percent of the units
to be made available at an affordable housing cost to very low income households.
(S.J.M.C. § 5.08.400 A.2..) The provision relating to rental units, however,
explicitly provides that it ―shall be operative [only] at such time as current
appellate case law in Palmer/Sixth Street Properties, L.P. v. City of Los Angeles,
175 Cal.App.4th 1396 (2d Dist. 2009) is overturned, disapproved, or depublished
by a court of competent jurisdiction or modified by the state legislature to
authorize control of rents of inclusionary units.‖ (Ibid.)


In the 2009 decision in Palmer/Sixth Street Properties, L.P. v. City of Los

Angeles, supra, 175 Cal.App.4th 1396 1410-1411 (Palmer/Sixth Street
Properties
), the Court of Appeal held that the vacancy decontrol provisions of the
Costa-Hawkins Rental Housing Act (Civ. Code, § 1954.53, subd. (a)) — that
permit residential landlords, except in specified circumstances, to establish the
initial rental rate for a dwelling or unit — precluded the City of Los Angeles from
enforcing a provision of its mandatory inclusionary housing ordinance that
required the developer of a residential rental development to rent some of the
rental units at a specified below market, affordable rental rate. The provision of
the San Jose ordinance in question recognizes that unless Palmer/Sixth Street
Properties
is judicially overturned or legislatively modified, the provisions of the
San Jose ordinance applicable to rental units, limiting the initial rent that a
developer can charge for a newly constructed residential rental unit, cannot be
enforced.


Although, in light of Palmer/Sixth Street Properties, the provisions of the

ordinance are not operative as to new rental units, when a residential development
includes both for-sale and rental units, the ordinance provides that its provisions
applicable to for-sale units shall apply to the portion of the development that
consists of for-sale units. (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.440.)

15

ordinance provides that when a developer chooses one of the alternative

compliance options, the inclusionary housing requirement increases to no less than

20 percent of the total units in the residential development, as contrasted with the

no less than 15 percent requirement that applies to on-site inclusionary units.

(S.J.M.C. § 5.08.500 B.) The alternative compliance options include:

(1) constructing off-site affordable for-sale units (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.510 A.),

(2) paying an in lieu fee based on the median sales price of a housing unit

affordable to a moderate income family (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.520), (3) dedicating land

equal in value to the applicable in lieu fee (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.530), or (4) acquiring

and rehabilitating a comparable number of inclusionary units that are affordable to

low or very low income households. (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.550.)

As additional incentives to encourage developers to comply with the

ordinance by providing affordable units on site, the ordinance permits a developer

who provides all of the required affordable units on the same site as the market

rate units to apply for and obtain a variety of economically beneficial incentives,

including (1) a density bonus that meets the requirements of Government Code

section 65915 et seq.,7 (2) a reduction in the number of parking spaces otherwise

required by the San Jose Municipal Code, (3) a reduction in minimum set-back

requirements, and (4) financial subsidies and assistance from the city in the sale of

the affordable units. (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.450.)


7

The density bonus provisions of Government Code section 65915 are very

detailed, specifying a variable bonus depending upon the household income
category to be served (very low income, low income, moderate income) and the
percentage of units the developer agrees to include in its proposed project. (Gov.
Code, § 65915, subd. (f).)

16

The ordinance also addresses the characteristics of the affordable units to be

constructed on site. The ordinance requires that such units have the same quality

of exterior design and comparable square footage and bedroom count as market

rate units (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.470 B., F.), but permits some different ―unit types‖ of

affordable units (for example, in developments with detached single-family market

rate units, the affordable units may be attached single-family units or may be

placed on smaller lots than the market rate units) (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.470 E.), and

also allows the affordable units to have different, but functionally equivalent,

interior finishes, features, and amenities, compared with the market rate units.

(S.J.M.C. § 5.08.470 C.)

The ordinance additionally contains a number of provisions intended to

ensure that the number of affordable housing units required by the ordinance is not

lost upon resale of an affordable unit. To this end, the ordinance requires that the

guidelines to be adopted by city officials to implement the ordinance ―shall

include standard documents . . . to ensure the continued affordability of the

inclusionary units approved for each residential development.‖ (S.J.M.C.

§ 5.08.600 A.) Such documents may include, but are not limited to, ―inclusionary

housing agreements, regulatory agreements, promissory notes, deeds of trust,

resale restrictions, rights of first refusal, options to purchase, and/or other

documents,‖ and shall be recorded against the residential development, all

inclusionary units, and any site subject to the provisions of the ordinance. (Ibid.)

The ordinance further provides that such documents shall include ―subordinate

shared appreciation documents permitting the city to recapture at resale the

difference between the market rate value of the inclusionary unit and the

affordable housing cost, plus a share of appreciation realized from an unrestricted

sale in such amounts as deemed necessary by the city to replace the inclusionary

unit.‖ (Ibid.) The ordinance specifies that all inclusionary units ―shall remain

17

affordable to the targeted income group for no less than the time periods set forth

in California Health and Safety Code Sections 33413(c)(1) and (2)‖ (S.J.M.C.

§ 5.08.600 B.),8 and that ―all promissory note repayments, shared appreciation

payments, or other payments collected under this section‖ shall be deposited in the

City of San Jose affordable housing fee fund (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.600 C.), from which

funds may be expended exclusively to provide housing affordable to extremely

low, very low, lower and moderate income households. (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.700 B.)

The ordinance further contains a waiver provision, declaring that the

ordinance‘s requirements may be ―waived, adjusted, or reduced‖ by the city ―if an

applicant shows, based on substantial evidence, that there is no reasonable

relationship between the impact of a proposed residential development and the

requirements of this chapter, or that applying the requirements of this chapter

would take property in violation of the United States or California Constitutions.‖

(S.J.M.C. § 5.08.720 A.) This section goes on to provide that ―[t]he waiver,

adjustment or reduction may be approved only to the extent necessary to avoid an

unconstitutional result, after adoption of written findings, based on substantial

evidence, supporting the determinations required by this section.‖ (S.J.M.C.

§ 5.08.720 E.)


8

Health and Safety Code section 33413, subdivision (c)(1) provides that

affordable units shall remain available at affordable cost for not less than 45 years
for home ownership units. Health and Safety Code section 33413,
subdivision (c)(2) allows the sale of such units prior to the expiration of 45 years
for a higher than affordable cost but only under a program that protects the public
entity‘s affordable housing interest by providing for the deposit of an appropriate
amount of the proceeds of the sale into the entity‘s low and moderate income
housing fund.

18

Finally, although the ordinance was adopted in January 2010, the city

council, in recognition of the significant disruption in the local housing market

that had accompanied the nationwide recession, provided that the ordinance would

not become operative until the earlier of (1) six months following the first 12-

month consecutive period in which 2,500 residential building permits had been

issued by the city, with a minimum of 1,250 permits issued for dwelling units

outside the San Jose redevelopment area, or (2) January 1, 2013. (S.J.M.C.

§ 5.08.300.)

III. Lower court proceedings

On March 24, 2010, just two months after the ordinance was enacted,

CBIA filed the underlying lawsuit in this proceeding in superior court, seeking

invalidation of the ordinance. The complaint alleged that the ordinance was

invalid on its face because at no time prior to the adoption of the ordinance had the

city provided substantial evidence ―to demonstrate a reasonable relationship

between any adverse public impacts or needs for additional subsidized housing

units in the City ostensibly caused by or reasonably attributed to the development

of new residential developments of 20 units or more and the new affordable

housing exactions and conditions imposed on residential development by the

Ordinance.‖ The complaint maintained that the city‘s actions in enacting the

ordinance were ―unlawful, unconstitutional, and in violation of controlling state

and federal constitutional standards governing such exactions and conditions of

development approval, and the requirements applicable to such housing exactions

as set forth in San Remo Hotel L.P. v. City & County of San Francisco (2002) 27

Cal.4th 643, and Building Industry Association of Central California v. City of

Patterson (5th Dist. 2009) 171 Cal.App.4th 886.‖ The complaint sought a judicial

declaration that the ordinance is invalid, and injunctive relief prohibiting the city

from enforcing the ordinance.

19

Six nonprofit affordable housing organizations and a low-income resident

of San Jose sought leave to intervene in support of the challenged ordinance.9

Although CBIA opposed the motion, the trial court granted the motion and

permitted intervention.

In their pretrial briefs, both the city and interveners took issue with CBIA‘s

contention that a passage in this court‘s opinion in San Remo Hotel, supra, 27

Cal.4th 643, should properly be interpreted to apply to the San Jose affordable

housing ordinance at issue. Contrary to CBIA‘s claim that under San Remo Hotel

such an ordinance is valid only if the requirements that the ordinance imposes are

reasonably related to the adverse effects or impacts that are caused by or

attributable to the developments upon which the requirements are imposed, the

city and interveners maintained that the ordinance‘s validity is properly evaluated

under the ordinary standard of review applicable to legislative land use

regulations, namely, simply that the regulation‘s requirements must be reasonably

related to the municipality‘s interest in promoting the health, safety, and welfare of

the community. The city and interveners argued that under this ordinarily

applicable standard the challenged affordable housing ordinance was

unquestionably valid.

After extensive briefing, the superior court agreed with CBIA‘s legal

contentions, concluding that the ordinance was constitutionally invalid and

enjoining its enforcement. In its order, the court rejected the city‘s position that


9

The following nonprofit organizations sought intervention: Affordable

Housing Network of Santa Clara County, California Coalition for Rural Housing,
Housing California, Non-Profit Housing Association of Northern California, San
Diego Housing Federation, and the Southern California Association of NonProfit
Housing.

20

the inclusionary ordinance did not require a developer to dedicate or convey

property, and struck down the ordinance. The court determined that the city had

failed to show that there was evidence in the record ―demonstrating the

constitutionally required reasonable relationships between the deleterious impacts

of new residential developments and the new requirements to build and to dedicate

the affordable housing or pay the fees in lieu of such property conveyances.‖

The Court of Appeal reversed the superior court judgment. Initially, the

appellate court rejected CBIA‘s contention that the ordinance requires a developer

seeking a permit to ― ‗dedicate or convey property (new homes) for public

purposes,‘ or alternatively, pay a fee in lieu of ‗such compelled transfers of

property,‘ ‖ concluding that the ordinance ―does not prescribe a dedication.‖ The

appellate court then went on to agree with the city and interveners that the

ordinance‘s inclusionary housing requirements must properly be evaluated under

the standard ordinarily applicable to general, legislatively imposed land use

regulations, namely whether the ordinance‘s requirements bear a real and

substantial relation to the public welfare. The Court of Appeal determined that the

matter should be remanded to the trial court to permit that court to review CBIA‘s

challenge under the proper legal standard.

In the course of its opinion, the Court of Appeal rejected CBIA‘s reliance

upon the San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, and City of Patterson, supra, 171

Cal.App.4th 886, decisions. The Court of Appeal concluded that the passage in

San Remo Hotel relied upon by CBIA was intended to apply only to development

mitigation fees that are intended to mitigate the deleterious impact of a proposed

development, and that the passage does not apply to the affordable housing

requirements imposed by the challenged San Jose ordinance because those

requirements were not enacted for the purpose of mitigating the adverse impact of

new development but rather to enhance the public welfare by promoting the use of

21

available land for the development of housing that would be available to low and

moderate income households. The Court of Appeal similarly found the City of

Patterson decision inapposite, noting that the city in that case did not propose or

advocate any test different from the San Remo Hotel test, and that the City of

Patterson court did not analyze the issue by reference to the city‘s stated general

objective in imposing its affordable housing in lieu fee.

After the Court of Appeal decision, CBIA sought review in this court,

maintaining that the appellate opinion in this case directly conflicted with the

Court of Appeal decision in City of Patterson, supra, 171 Cal.App.4th 886, and

that City of Patterson was correctly decided. We granted review to determine the

soundness of the appellate court‘s ruling in this case.

In analyzing this question, we first consider an initial point that divided the

lower court decisions in this case — whether the conditions imposed by the San

Jose ordinance constitute ―exactions‖ for purposes of the federal and state takings

clauses and thus trigger the applicability of the unconstitutional conditions

doctrine. (See pt. IV., post.) Thereafter, we consider whether the passage in this

court‘s decision in San Remo Hotel, upon which CBIA relies, applies to the

conditions imposed by the challenged inclusionary housing ordinance. (See pt. V.,

post.)


IV. Does the San Jose inclusionary housing ordinance, in requiring

new residential developments to sell some of the proposed new units at an
affordable housing price, impose an “exaction” on developers’ property
under the takings clauses of the federal and California Constitutions, so as to
bring into play the unconstitutional conditions doctrine?


We begin with the well-established principle that under the California

Constitution a municipality has broad authority, under its general police power, to

regulate the development and use of real property within its jurisdiction to

promote the public welfare. (Cal. Const., art. XI, § 7; Big Creek Lumber Co. v.

22

County of Santa Cruz (2006) 38 Cal.4th 1139, 1151-1152.) The variety and range

of permissible land use regulations are extensive and familiar, including, for

example, restrictions on the types of activities for which such property may be

used (commercial or residential, or specific types of commercial ventures or

specific types of residential developments — single family, multiunit), limitations

on the density and size of permissible residential development (permissible lot

size, number of units per lot, minimum or maximum square footage of units,

number of bedrooms), required set-backs, aesthetic restrictions and requirements,

and price controls (for example, rent control). As a general matter, so long as a

land use restriction or regulation bears a reasonable relationship to the public

welfare, the restriction or regulation is constitutionally permissible. (See, e.g.,

Associated Home Builders etc., Inc. v. City of Livermore (1976) 18 Cal.3d 582,

604-607 (City of Livermore); Miller v. Board of Public Works (1925) 195 Cal.

477, 490; Schad v. Mount Ephraim (1981) 452 U.S. 61, 68; Euclid v. Amber

Realty Co. (1926) 272 U.S. 365 (Euclid).)

We review challenges to the exercise of such power deferentially. ―In

deciding whether a challenged [land use] ordinance reasonably relates to the

public welfare, the courts recognize that such ordinances are presumed to be

constitutional, and come before the court with every intendment in their favor.‖

(City of Livermore, supra, 18 Cal.3d at pp. 604-605.) Accordingly, a party

challenging the facial validity of a legislative land use measure ordinarily bears the

burden of demonstrating that the measure lacks a reasonable relationship to the

public welfare. (See, e.g., Goldblatt v. Hempstead (1962) 369 U.S. 590, 596;

Building Industry Assn. of Central California v. County of Stanislaus (2010) 190

Cal.App.4th 582, 591.) Nonetheless, as this court explained in City of Livermore,

supra, 18 Cal.3d at p. 609, although land use regulations are generally entitled to

deference, ―judicial deference is not judicial abdication. The ordinance must have

23

a real and substantial relation to the public welfare. [Citation.] There must be a

reasonable basis in fact, not in fancy, to support the legislative determination.

[Citation.] Although in many cases it will be ‗fairly debatable‘ [citation] that the

ordinance reasonably relates to the regional welfare, it cannot be assumed that a

land use ordinance can never be invalidated as an enactment in excess of the

police power.‖ (See also McKay Jewelers v. Bowron (1942) 19 Cal.2d 595, 600-

601; Skalko v. City of Sunnyvale (1939) 14 Cal.2d 213, 215-216.)

In the present case, however, CBIA contends that this traditional standard

of judicial review is not applicable and that the conditions that the ordinance

imposes upon a proposed new development are valid only if those conditions bear

a reasonable relationship to the amount of the city‘s need for affordable housing

that is attributable to the proposed development itself, rather than that the

ordinance‘s conditions bear a reasonable relationship to the public welfare of the

city and region as a whole. It also contends that the city, rather than the party

challenging the ordinance, bears the burden of proof regarding the validity of the

ordinance.

As already noted, although the precise nature and source of CBIA‘s

constitutional claim was somewhat opaque in earlier stages of this litigation, in its

briefing in this court CBIA has clarified that its facial constitutional challenge

rests upon the takings clauses of the United States and California Constitutions

(U.S. Const., 5th and 14th Amends.; Cal. Const., art. I, § 19),10 and, more


10

The Fifth Amendment of the United States Constitution provides in

relevant part: ―. . . nor shall private property be taken for public use without just
compensation.‖ The United States Supreme Court has long held that the takings
clause of the Fifth Amendment is made applicable to the states through the
Fourteenth Amendment. (Chicago, B. & Q. R. Co. v. Chicago (1897) 166 U.S.
226, 239.)


(footnote continued on next page)

24

specifically, on the claim ―that the Ordinance violates the unconstitutional

conditions doctrine, as applied to development exactions.‖ As we shall explain,

however, there can be no valid unconstitutional-conditions takings claim without a

government exaction of property, and the ordinance in the present case does not

effect an exaction. Rather, the ordinance is an example of a municipality‘s

permissible regulation of the use of land under its broad police power.

As a general matter, the unconstitutional conditions doctrine imposes

special restrictions upon the government‘s otherwise broad authority to condition

the grant of a privilege or benefit when a proposed condition requires the

individual to give up or refrain from exercising a constitutional right. (See, e.g.,

Perry v. Sindermann (1972) 408 U.S. 593, 597-598; Pickering v. Board of

Education (1968) 391 U.S. 563, 568.) In the takings context, the special

limitations imposed by the unconstitutional conditions doctrine upon which CBIA

relies derive from the United States Supreme Court‘s decisions in Nollan v.


(footnote continued from previous page)



Unlike the federal takings clause, which provides simply that private

property shall not be taken for public use without just compensation, the
California takings clause provides that private property shall not be taken or
damaged
for public use without just compensation. (Cal. Const., art. I, § 19,
subd. (a).) The governing California authorities make clear that the reference to
―damaged‖ in this constitutional provision refers to physical damage and does not
encompass the simple reduction in the value of real property that may result from
a land use restriction or regulation or other governmental action. (See, e.g.,
Customer Co. v. City of Sacramento (1995) 10 Cal.4th 368, 376-378; HFH Ltd. v.
Superior Court
(1975) 15 Cal.3d 508, 517-518; Allegretti & Co. v. County of
Imperial
(2006) 138 Cal.App.4th 1261, 1278-1279.) In contexts comparable to
that at issue in this case, past cases of this court have interpreted the state takings
clause ―congruently‖ with the federal takings clause. (See, e.g., San Remo Hotel,
supra, 27 Cal.4th at p. 664.)

25

California Coastal Commission (1987) 483 U.S. 825 (Nollan) and Dolan v. City of

Tigard (1994) 512 U.S. 374 (Dolan).

In both Nollan, supra, 483 U.S. 825, and Dolan, supra, 512 U.S. 374, the

high court considered the validity of ad hoc administrative decisions regarding

individual land-use permit applications that required a property owner, as a

condition of obtaining a sought-after permit, to dedicate a portion of the property

to public use. In Nollan, the California Coastal Commission had conditioned its

grant of a permit to allow the property owner to demolish a small beachfront

bungalow and construct a three-bedroom residence upon the owner‘s agreement to

grant an easement to the public to enter and cross the owner‘s beachfront property

near the water‘s edge. In Dolan, the city had conditioned its grant of a permit to

allow the property owner to substantially increase the size of its existing retail

business upon the owner‘s agreement to give a strip of the property to the city for

use as part of a public flood-control greenway and bike path.

In Nollan, supra, 483 U.S. 825, in explaining why the takings clause

justified special scrutiny of the coastal commission‘s imposition of the challenged

permit condition at issue in that case, the high court began its analysis by

observing: ―Had California simply required the Nollans to make an easement

across their beachfront available to the public on a permanent basis in order to

increase public access to the beach, rather than conditioning their permit to rebuild

their house on their agreeing to do so, we have no doubt there would have been a

taking.‖ (Id. at p. 831.) Similarly, in Dolan, the high court noted that ―had the

city simply required petitioner to dedicate a strip of land . . . for public use, rather

than conditioning the grant of her permit to redevelop her property on such a

dedication, a taking would have occurred.‖ (Dolan, supra, 512 U.S. at p. 384.)

Because under the takings clause a property owner has the right to be paid just

compensation when the government takes his or her property for public use, the

26

court in Nollan declared that special scrutiny of a governmental action is

warranted ―where the actual conveyance of property is made a condition for the

lifting of a land-use restriction, since in that context there is heightened risk that

the [government‘s] purpose is avoidance of the compensation requirement, rather

than the stated police-power objective‖ upon which the condition is ostensibly

based. (Nollan, at p. 841, italics added.) Thereafter, the Nollan and Dolan

decisions proceeded to explain and describe the nature and extent of the special

scrutiny that is called for under the takings clause when the government conditions

the grant of a land use permit on the property owner‘s agreement to dedicate a

portion of its property for public use without the payment of just compensation.

Under Nollan and Dolan, the government may impose such a condition only when

the government demonstrates that there is an ―essential nexus‖ and ―rough

proportionality‖ between the required dedication and the projected impact of the

proposed land use. (See Nollan, supra, at pp. 837-840; Dolan, supra, at pp. 388-

395.)

More recently, in Koontz v. St. Johns River Water Mgmt. Dist. (2013) 570

U.S. __ [186 L.Ed.2d 697] (Koontz), the high court held that the Nollan/Dolan test

applies not only when the government conditions approval of a land use permit on

the property owner‘s dedication of a portion of the property for public use but also

when it conditions approval of such a permit upon the owner‘s payment of money.

In Koontz, the property owner applied for a permit to develop a portion of an

undeveloped parcel of land, most of which was classified as wetlands by the state.

In his application, the owner agreed to dedicate a portion of the property to the

local public water management district as a conservation easement, but the district

considered the size of the property owner‘s proposed conservation easement to be

inadequate and instead proposed that the property owner either dedicate a larger

portion of the property as a conservation easement or, alternatively, pay for the

27

improvement of other district-owned wetlands within several miles of the owner‘s

property. The property owner refused to accede to the district‘s proposal, and

brought an action in Florida state court against the district, contending among

other matters that the district‘s proposal that he pay a sum of money as an

alternative to dedicating an additional portion of his property was itself subject to

the Nollan/Dolan test and thus that the district was required to show that the

amount of money in question satisfied the ―essential nexus‖ and ―rough

proportionality‖ requirements set forth in those decisions. The Florida Supreme

Court rejected the property owner‘s contention on the ground that a permit

condition that requires a property owner to pay or spend money, as contrasted with

a condition that requires the owner to give the public a tangible interest in real

property, does not provide a basis for a takings claim, and thus was not subject to

the Nollan/Dolan test.

In Koontz, supra, 570 U.S. at pages __-__ [186 L.Ed.2d at pp. 712-717], a

majority of the United States Supreme Court disagreed with the Florida Supreme

Court‘s conclusion on this point. The majority began its analysis of this issue by

noting ―as an initial matter that if we accepted this argument [that the

Nollan/Dolan test does not apply to a permit condition that requires the property

owner to pay money] it would be very easy for land-use permitting officials to

evade the limitations of Nollan and Dolan. Because the government need only

provide a permit applicant with one alternative that satisfies the nexus and rough

proportionality standards, a permitting authority wishing to exact an easement

could simply give the owner a choice of either surrendering an easement or

making a payment equal to the easement‘s value. . . . For that reason and those

that follow, we reject respondent‘s argument and hold that so-called ‗monetary

exactions‘ must satisfy the nexus and rough proportionality requirements of

Nollan and Dolan.‖ (Id. at p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 713].)

28

It is clear from the decision in Koontz, supra, 570 U.S. __ [186 L.Ed.2d

697], that the Nollan/Dolan standard applies to the type of ―so-called ‗monetary

exactions‘ ‖ (Koonz, at p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d p. 713]) involved in Koontz itself —

that is, a monetary payment that is a substitute for the property owner‘s dedication

of property to the public and that is intended to mitigate the environmental impact

of the proposed project. However, the full range of monetary land-use permit

conditions to which the Nollan/Dolan test applies under the Koontz decision

remains at least somewhat ambiguous.11 Nonetheless, the Koontz decision


11

As the passage quoted in the text illustrates (see Koontz, supra, 570 U.S. at

p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 713]), at times the court in Koontz appears to have relied
upon the special risks imposed by monetary conditions, like the monetary payment
at issue in that case, that are offered by a permitting authority as an alternative to
or substitute for the actual dedication of property for public use
. (See id. at p. __
[186 L.Ed.2d at p. 713]; see also id. at p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 716] [noting that
―respondent has maintained throughout this litigation that it considered
petitioner‘s money to be a substitute for his deeding to the public a conservation
easement on a larger parcel of undeveloped land‖].) At other points, however, the
opinion in Koontz speaks more broadly and suggests that the Nollan/Dolan test
applies to monetary permit conditions even when the monetary payment is not
imposed in lieu of a requirement that the property owner dedicate a property
interest. (See Koontz, supra, at pp. __-__ [186 L.Ed.2d at pp. 713-714] [―the
demand for money at issue here did ‗operate upon . . . an identified property
interest‘ by directing the owner of a particular piece of property to make a
monetary payment. [Citation.] In this case . . . the monetary obligation burdened
petitioner‘s ownership of a specific parcel of land.‖]; id. at p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d at
p. 714] [―when the government commands the relinquishment of funds linked to a
specific, identifiable property interest such as a bank account or parcel of real
property, a ‗per se [takings] approach‘ is the proper mode of analysis under the
Court‘s precedent.‖].) For the reasons discussed hereafter, we need not, and do
not, resolve this ambiguity in the present case.

An additional ambiguity arises from the fact that the monetary condition in

Koontz, like the conditions at issue in Nollan and Dolan, was imposed by the
district on an ad hoc basis upon an individual permit applicant, and was not a
legislatively prescribed condition that applied to a broad class of permit applicants.
In this respect, the money payment at issue in Koontz was similar to the monetary


(footnote continued on next page)

29

explicitly acknowledges that ―[a] predicate for any unconstitutional conditions

claim is that the government could not have constitutionally ordered the person

asserting the claim to do what it attempted to pressure that person into doing.‖

(Koontz, supra, at p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 712].) Or, in other words, the condition

is one that would have constituted a taking of property without just compensation

if it were imposed by the government on a property owner outside of the permit

process. (Id. at p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d at pp. 712-713, 714]; see Lingle v. Chevron

U.S.A. Inc. (2005) 544 U.S. 528, 547 (Lingle) [Nollan and Dolan both involved

―dedications of property so onerous that, outside the exactions context, they would

be deemed per se physical takings‖].) Nothing in Koontz suggests that the

unconstitutional conditions doctrine under Nollan and Dolan would apply where

the government simply restricts the use of property without demanding the

conveyance of some identifiable protected property interest (a dedication of


(footnote continued from previous page)

recreational-mitigation fee at issue in this court‘s decision in Ehrlich v. City of
Culver City
(1996) 12 Cal.4th 854 (Ehrlich), where we held that because of the
greater risk of arbitrariness and abuse that is present when a monetary condition is
imposed on an individual permit applicant on an ad hoc basis, the validity of the
ad hoc fee imposed in that case should properly be evaluated under the
Nollan/Dolan test. (Ehrlich, supra, at pp. 874-885 (plur. opn. of Arabian, J.); id.
at pp. 899-901 (conc. opn. of Mosk, J.); id. at pp. 903, 907 (conc. & dis. opn. of
Kennard, J.); id. at p. 912 (conc. & dis. opn. of Werdegar, J.).) The Koontz
decision does not purport to decide whether the Nollan/Dolan test is applicable to
legislatively prescribed monetary permit conditions that apply to a broad class of
proposed developments. (See Koontz, supra, 570 U.S. at p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d at
p. 723] (dis. opn. of Kagan, J.).) Our court has held that legislatively prescribed
monetary fees that are imposed as a condition of development are not subject to
the Nollan/Dolan test. (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at pp. 663-671; see
Santa Monica Beach, Ltd. v. Superior Court (1999) 19 Cal.4th 952, 966-967
(Santa Monica Beach).)

30

property or the payment of money) as a condition of approval. It is the

governmental requirement that the property owner convey some identifiable

property interest that constitutes a so-called ―exaction‖ under the takings clause

and that brings the unconstitutional conditions doctrine into play. (See Lingle,

supra, at pp. 546-547; Monterey v. Del Monte Dunes at Monterey, Ltd. (1999) 526

U.S. 687, 702 [―[W]e have not extended the rough-proportionality test of Dolan

beyond the special context of exactions — land-use decisions conditioning

approval of development on the dedication of property to public use.‖].)

In the present case, contrary to CBIA‘s contention, the San Jose

inclusionary housing ordinance does not violate the unconstitutional conditions

doctrine because there is no exaction — the ordinance does not require a

developer to give up a property interest for which the government would have

been required to pay just compensation under the takings clause outside of the

permit process. As summarized above, the principal requirement that the

challenged ordinance imposes upon a developer is that the developer sell 15

percent of its on-site for-sale units at an affordable housing price. This condition

does not require the developer to dedicate any portion of its property to the public

or to pay any money to the public. Instead, like many other land use regulations,

this condition simply places a restriction on the way the developer may use its

property by limiting the price for which the developer may offer some of its units

for sale. (See, e.g., Yee v. Escondido (1992) 503 U.S. 519, 532 (Yee) [describing

mobilehome park rent control ordinance as ―a regulation of [the mobilehome park

owners‘] use of their property‖].) Contrary to CBIA‘s contention, such a

requirement does not constitute an exaction for purposes of the Nollan/Dolan line

of decisions and does not trigger application of the unconstitutional conditions

doctrine.

31

Rather than being an exaction, the ordinance falls within what we have

already described as municipalities‘ general broad discretion to regulate the use of

real property to serve the legitimate interests of the general public and the

community at large. For example, municipalities may designate certain areas of a

city where only residential units may be built and other areas where only

commercial projects are permitted. (See, e.g., Euclid, supra, 272 U.S. 365;

Lockard v. City of Los Angeles (1949) 33 Cal.2d 453, 460.) If a municipality finds

that it is in the public interest, it may specify where certain types of retail

establishments may be operated and other areas where they may not. (See, e.g.,

Hernandez v. City of Hanford (2007) 41 Cal.4th 279, 296-298 & fn. 10.) If a

municipality concludes that the city already has a sufficient number of a specific

type of business in a particular neighborhood — for example, adult entertainment

businesses — it may prohibit other property owners from using their property in

that area for such businesses. (See, e.g., Young v. American Mini Theatres (1976)
427 U.S. 50; Renton v. Playtime Theatres, Inc. (1986) 475 U.S. 41.) Similarly, if a

municipality determines that a particular neighborhood or the community in

general is in special need of a specific type of residential development or business

establishment — such as a multiunit residential project or a retail shopping center

— it may adopt land use regulations to serve such a need. (See, e.g., Ensign

Bickford Realty Corp. v. City Council (1977) 68 Cal.App.3d 467, 477-478.) In

addition, of course, a municipality may impose land use limitations on the height

of buildings, set-back requirements, density limits (lot size and number of units

per lot), bedroom requirements and a variety of other use restrictions. (See, e.g.,

Griffin Development Co. v. City of Oxnard (1985) 39 Cal.3d 256, 265-266.)

As a general matter, so long as a land use regulation does not constitute a

physical taking or deprive a property owner of all viable economic use of the

property, such a restriction does not violate the takings clause insofar as it governs

32

a property owner‘s future use of his or her property,12 except in the unusual

circumstance in which the use restriction is properly found to go ―too far‖ and to

constitute a ―regulatory taking‖ under the ad hoc, multifactored test discussed by

the United States Supreme Court in Penn Central Transp. Co. v. New York City

(1978) 438 U.S. 104 (Penn Central). (See Lingle, supra, 544 U.S. at pp. 538-

539.)13 Where a restriction on the use of property would not constitute a taking of

property without just compensation if imposed outside of the permit process, a

permit condition imposing such a use restriction does not require a permit

applicant to give up the constitutional right to just compensation in order to obtain

the permit and thus does not constitute ―an exaction‖ so as to bring into play the

unconstitutional conditions doctrine. (See, e.g., Powell v. County of Humboldt

(2014) 222 Cal.App.4th 1424, 1435-1441.)

As noted, the legislative history of the ordinance in question establishes that

the City of San Jose found there was a significant and increasing need for

affordable housing in the city to meet the city‘s regional share of housing needs

under the California Housing Element Law and that the public interest would best

be served if new affordable housing were integrated into economically diverse


12

Special considerations and principles come into play with regard to a

municipality‘s application of such limitations to existing uses that do not conform
to the municipality‘s newly imposed restrictions — that is, to preexisting
nonconforming uses. (See generally 8 Witkin, Summary of Cal. Law (10th ed.
2005) Constitutional Law, §§ 1040-1045, pp. 636-645.) The ordinance at issue
applies only to residential units that are to be constructed or rehabilitated in the
future.

13

The factors identified in Penn Central include the ―economic impact of the

regulation on the claimant,‖ ―the extent to which the regulation has interfered with
distinct investment-backed expectations,‖ and ―the character of the governmental
action.‖ (Penn Central, supra, 438 U.S. at p. 124.)

33

development projects, and that it enacted the challenged ordinance in order to

further these objectives. The objectives of increasing the amount of affordable

housing in the city to comply with the Housing Element Law and of locating such

housing in economically diverse developments are unquestionably constitutionally

permissible purposes. (See, e.g., Santa Monica Beach, supra, 19 Cal.4th at p. 970;

Home Builders Assn. v. City of Napa (2009) 90 Cal.App.4th 188, 195 (City of

Napa).) CBIA does not argue otherwise.

There are a variety of conditions or restrictions that a municipality could

impose on new residential development in an effort to increase the community‘s

stock of affordable housing and promote economically diverse residential

developments. For example, a municipality might attempt to achieve these

objectives by requiring all new residential developments to include a specified

percentage of studio, one-bedroom, or small-square-footage units, on the theory

that smaller units are more likely to be affordable to low or moderate income

households than larger units. Although such use restrictions might well reduce the

value of undeveloped property or lessen the profits a developer could obtain in the

absence of such requirements, CBIA cites no authority, and we are aware of none,

suggesting that such use restrictions would constitute a taking of property outside

the permit process or that a permit condition that imposes such use restrictions on

a proposed development would constitute an exaction under the takings clause that

would be subject to the Nollan/Dolan test.

Here, the challenged ordinance seeks to increase the city‘s stock of

affordable housing and promote economically diverse residential projects by

placing controls on the sales price of a portion of a developer‘s on-site for-sale

units rather than by placing restrictions on the size or other features of a portion of

the for-sale units. But the fact that the ordinance imposes price controls rather

than other use restrictions in order to accomplish its legitimate purposes does not

34

render such price controls an exaction or support application of a constitutionally

based judicial standard of review that is more demanding than that applied to other

land use regulations. The governing federal and state authorities plainly establish

that price controls, like other forms of regulation, are, as a general matter, a

constitutionally permissible means to achieve a municipality‘s legitimate public

purposes. (See, e.g., Nebbia v. New York (1934) 291 U.S. 502, 539 [―Price

control, like any other form of regulation, is unconstitutional only if arbitrary,

discriminatory, or demonstrably irrelevant to the policy the legislature is free to

adopt, and hence an unnecessary and unwarranted interference with individual

liberty‖]; Permian Basin Area Rate Cases (1968) 390 U.S. 747, 768 [―It is plain

that the Constitution does not forbid the imposition, in appropriate circumstances,

of maximum prices upon commercial and other activities. A legislative power to

create price ceilings has, in ‘countries where the common law prevails,’ been

‘customary from time immemorial‘ ‖ (italics added)]; accord, Pennell v. San Jose

(1988) 485 U.S. 1, 11-14 (Pennell); Yee, supra, 503 U.S. at pp. 528-530; Santa

Monica Beach, supra, 19 Cal.4th at p. 967; Kavanau v. Santa Monica Rent

Control Bd. (1997) 16 Cal.4th 761, 771-777 (Kavanau); Calfarm Ins. Co. v.

Deukmejian (1989) 48 Cal.3d 805, 816 (Calfarm); Birkenfeld v. City of Berkeley

(1976) 17 Cal.3d 129, 165 (Birkenfeld).)

Furthermore, as we explained in Santa Monica Beach, supra, 19 Cal.4th

952, the United States Supreme Court has held that one of the constitutionally

permissible purposes that justifies the imposition of limits on the rent a landlord

may charge his or her tenants is ―that of ‗ ―prevent[ing] excessive and

unreasonable rent increases‖ caused by the ―growing shortage of and increasing

demand for housing‖ ‘ within a municipality.‖ (Id. at p. 969, quoting Pennell,

supra, 485 U.S. at p. 12.) There is no reason that a municipality‘s comparable

interest in combatting the excessive sale prices of housing that are caused by the

35

growing shortage of and increasing demand for housing, and that deny moderate

and lower income families the opportunity to reside within the city, does not

similarly justify the city‘s imposition of price controls on a portion of the units that

are offered for sale in a proposed new residential development. (Accord, Pennell,

supra, at pp. 12-13 [recognizing that ―a legitimate and rational goal of price or rate

regulation is the protection of consumer welfare‖ and upholding a rent control

ordinance that permitted ― ‗hardship to a tenant‘ ‖ to be considered in determining

the reasonableness of a landlord‘s proposed rent increase].)

A municipality‘s authority to impose price controls on developers is, of

course, unquestionably subject to constitutional limits. In this court‘s decision in

Kavanau, supra, 16 Cal.4th at pages 771-777, we discussed the constitutional

restrictions placed on price controls by the due process and takings clauses, and

explained that such controls would be unconstitutional if they are found to be

confiscatory, that is, if they deny a property owner a fair and reasonable return on

its property. (See Birkenfeld, supra, 17 Cal.3d at p. 165; Calfarm, supra, 48

Cal.3d at pp. 816-817.) In this case, however, the ordinance has not yet been

applied to any proposed development, and there is no indication that application of

price controls on 15 percent of a development‘s on-sale units, along with the

availability of economically advantageous density bonuses, exemptions from on-

site parking requirements, and financial subsidies, would produce a confiscatory

result. (See Penn Central, supra, 438 U.S. at pp. 130-131 [― ‗Taking‘

jurisprudence does not divide a single parcel into discrete segments and attempt to

determine whether rights in a particular segment have been entirely abrogated. In

deciding whether a particular governmental action has effected a taking, this Court

focuses rather both on the character of the action and on the nature and extent of

the interference with rights in the parcel as a whole.‖].) Indeed, in this facial

36

challenge to the ordinance, CBIA does not claim that the requirements imposed by

the ordinance will have a confiscatory effect.

Further, although we explained in Kavanau that past decisions have

generally applied a ―confiscatory‖ analysis to challenges to price controls that are

premised on either the takings clause or the due process clause — ―focusing on the

regulation‘s impact and investors‘ ability to earn a fair return‖ (Kavanau, supra,

16 Cal.4th at p. 776, citing Duquesne Light Co. v. Barasch (1989) 488 U.S. 299,

305; FCC v. Florida Power Corp. (1987) 480 U.S. 245, 250-254) — we also

observed in Kavanau that several high court cases indicate that other takings

analyses also apply to price controls (Kavanau, supra, at p. 777, citing Yee, supra,

503 U.S. at p. 529; Pennell, supra, 485 U.S. at pp. 8-14.) These latter cases

indicate that price controls may be impermissible if found to constitute a

―regulatory taking‖ under the ad hoc, multifactored test set forth in Penn Central,

supra, 438 U.S. 104. (See, e.g., Yee, supra, 503 U.S. at p. 529-531.) Here,

however, CBIA has expressly disclaimed any reliance on the Penn Central

doctrine.

As we have explained, an ordinance that places nonconfiscatory price

controls on the sale of residential units and does not amount to a regulatory taking

would not constitute a taking of property without just compensation even if the

price controls were applied to a property owner who had not sought a land use

permit. Accordingly, the inclusionary housing ordinance‘s imposition of such

price controls as a condition of a development permit does not constitute the

imposition of an exaction for purposes of the unconstitutional conditions doctrine

under the takings clause.

In maintaining its contrary view that the San Jose inclusionary housing

requirement constitutes an exaction that compels a developer to convey a property

interest to the city as a condition of development, CBIA relies primarily upon the

37

discussion of exactions in this court‘s recent decision in Sterling Park, L.P. v. City

of Palo Alto (2013) 57 Cal.4th 1193, 1207 (Sterling Park), a case which also

involved an affordable housing ordinance. In part VI., post, we describe the

specific legal issue that was presented in Sterling Park and this court‘s holding in

that case, and explain why CBIA‘s reliance on the Sterling Park decision itself is

not well founded. At this juncture, we explain why, whether or not the San Jose

inclusionary housing requirement at issue here is properly viewed as an exaction

for purposes of the procedural statute that was at issue in Sterling Park, the San

Jose inclusionary housing requirement does not require a developer to convey or

dedicate to the city a property interest as a condition of development and therefore

is not an exaction for purposes of the unconstitutional conditions doctrine as

applied in the takings context.

CBIA first contends that the ordinance should be viewed as requiring the

owner to convey property to the city as a condition of development because, by

requiring the developer to sell at a below market (affordable) price a portion of the

units that it could otherwise sell at market value, the ordinance ―divests the owner

of the difference, in money, between the market value of the property and the

affordable price of the property.‖ To begin with, however, because the San Jose

ordinance makes available a number of economically beneficial incentives —

including a density bonus, a reduction in parking requirements, and potential

financial subsidies — to developers who choose to comply with the affordable

housing requirements by providing on-site affordable housing units, it is not the

case that the San Jose ordinance will necessarily reduce a developer‘s revenue or

profit from what the developer could earn by selling all of the units at market rate,

or will do so either in the ―great majority of cases‖ (see San Remo Hotel, supra, 27

Cal.4th at p. 673), frequently, or, indeed, in any instance. In this facial challenge

38

to the ordinance, CBIA has not and cannot show that the ordinance will have such

an effect.14

In any event, it is well established that the fact that a land use regulation

may diminish the market value that the property would command in the absence of

the regulation — i.e., that the regulation reduces the money that the property

owner can obtain upon sale of the property — does not constitute a taking of the

diminished value of the property. Most land use regulations or restrictions reduce

the value of property; in this regard the affordable housing requirement at issue

here is no different from limitations on density, unit size, number of bedrooms,

required set-backs, or building heights. (See, e.g., Griffin Development Co. v. City

of Oxnard, supra, 39 Cal.3d at p. 267 [―most land use regulations have ‗the

inevitable effect of reducing the value of regulated properties‘ ‖].) Although the

magnitude of a regulation‘s economic impact upon a property owner is one factor

that is relevant in determining whether there is a regulatory taking under the Penn

Central test (see Penn Central, supra, 438 U.S. at p. 124), as already noted CBIA

explicitly does not contend that the ordinance constitutes a regulatory taking under

Penn Central. Past cases establish that the potential reduction in a developer‘s

profit does not in itself amount to a taking or a required dedication of property or

render the ordinance‘s price controls an exaction of property, as CBIA asserts.

(Penn Central, supra, at pp. 124-126; Penna. Coal Co. v. Mahon (1922) 260 U.S.

393, 413 [―Government hardly could go on if to some extent values incident to

property could not be diminished without paying for every such change in the


14

Because the ordinance will not necessarily lead to a reduction in the profit a

developer would obtain in the absence of the ordinance, CBIA cannot properly
assert that the ordinance, on its face, requires a developer to ―subsidize‖ those
households who purchase affordable units.

39

general law‖]; Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, supra, 390 U.S. at p. 769 [―No

constitutional objection arises from the imposition of maximum prices merely

because . . . the value of regulated property is reduced as a consequence of

regulation‖]; Fisher v. City of Berkeley (1984) 37 Cal.3d 644, 685-686.)

CBIA additionally maintains that the challenged ordinance does constitute

an exaction because it assertedly requires a developer to convey a property interest

to the city by virtue of the section of the ordinance that is intended to ensure that

the units that are initially made available as affordable housing units will continue

to be affordable in the future, or at least that the city will retain the same number

of affordable units upon resale. (S.J.M.C. § 5.08.600.) Contrary to CBIA‘s

assertion, however, this provision of the ordinance does not require a developer to

convey a property interest to the city. This feature of the ordinance operates in the

future on a person who has purchased an affordable unit, rather than on the

developer, placing a restriction on the affordable unit owner‘s use of his or her

property. Because this feature of the ordinance places no additional requirement

or burden on the developer, it clearly does not take, or impose an exaction upon,

the developer’s property. Unlike the Palo Alto inclusionary housing ordinance at

issue in Sterling Park, supra, 57 Cal.4th at page 1207, which CBIA analogizes to

the challenged ordinance, the San Jose ordinance does not require that the

developer grant the city an option to purchase each affordable unit when the unit is

up for sale or resale.15

15

Although an option to purchase is one type of document that may be

included to ensure the continued affordability of an affordable unit under the San
Jose ordinance, the applicable section of the ordinance does not require the
developer to grant an option to purchase to the city either on the initial sale or
resale of an affordable housing unit, and the section lists a large number of
alternative documents and mechanisms that may be used to preserve the number of
affordable housing units. (See S.J.M.C. § 5.08.600 A., quoted ante, pp. 17-18.)


(footnote continued on next page)

40

Moreover, CBIA does not contend that the section of the ordinance in

question constitutes a taking of an affordable unit owner’s property that requires

just compensation, and no such claim could plausibly be made. Under the

provision in question, an individual who is permitted to purchase an affordable

housing unit at a below market, affordable housing price will do so on the explicit

condition and clear understanding that if and when he or she sells the unit, he or

she is required to sell the unit at an affordable housing price, and that if, instead,

the unit is sold at market rate, under the ―shared appreciation document[]‖ that

must be agreed upon by the purchaser, ―the difference between the market rate

value of the inclusionary unit and the affordable housing cost, plus a share of

appreciation realized from an unrestricted sale in such amounts as deemed

necessary by the city to replace the inclusionary unit‖ must be placed into an

affordable housing fund that is to be used exclusively to provide housing to lower

and moderate income households. (S.J.M.C. §§ 5.08.600 A., 5.08.700.)16 Just as

the ordinance‘s restriction on the developer‘s use of its property does not

constitute a compensable taking or exaction (see, ante, pp. 32-37), an individual

who has purchased an affordable housing unit under the use restriction imposed by

this section of the ordinance cannot tenably claim that such property has been

taken without just compensation when he or she is subsequently required, upon


(footnote continued from previous page)

Accordingly, in this facial challenge, the San Jose ordinance cannot properly be
equated with the ordinance at issue in Sterling Park.

16

Thus, like the long-term rental unit in-lieu fee that was upheld by this court

in San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, the captured amount will be utilized to
replace the affordable housing unit that would be lost if such a unit is resold at
market rate, directly offsetting the adverse impact that such resale would have on
the number of existing affordable housing units in the city.

41

resale of the unit, to comply with the use restriction — a restriction that obviously

is reasonably related to preserving the affordable housing policy from which the

affordable housing unit owner has directly benefited.

In addition, contrary to CBIA‘s contention, the fact that the ordinance

requires restrictions upon resale to be recorded against the residential development

and all inclusionary units does not transform these requirements into property

interests possessed by the city. Recordation simply assures that would-be

purchasers of the affordable units are on notice regarding the restrictions relating

to resale and is no different from the routine recording of other types of land use

restrictions that are intended to continue for a specified period of time.

In sum, for all of the foregoing reasons, the basic requirement imposed by

the challenged ordinance — conditioning the grant of a development permit for

new developments of more than 20 units upon a developer‘s agreement to offer for

sale at an affordable housing price at least 15 percent of the on-site for-sale units

— does not constitute an exaction for purposes of the takings clause so as to bring

into play the unconstitutional conditions doctrine under the Nollan, Dolan, and

Koontz decisions.

Finally, the Koontz decision further makes clear that so long as a permitting

authority offers a property owner at least one alternative means of satisfying a

condition that does not violate the takings clause, the property owner has not been

subjected to an unconstitutional condition. (Koontz, supra, 570 U.S. at p. __ [186

L.Ed.2d at pp. 712, 713].) Accordingly, because the requirement that a developer

offer at least 15 percent of a development‘s for-sale units at an affordable housing

price does not violate the Nollan/Dolan doctrine, it follows that the affordable

housing requirement of the San Jose ordinance as a whole — including the

voluntary off-site options and in lieu fee that the ordinance makes available to a

42

developer — does not impose an unconstitutional condition in violation of the

takings clause.

V. Does the passage in San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, 671,

relied on by CBIA, apply to the affordable housing condition imposed by San
Jose’s inclusionary housing ordinance?


CBIA also rests its facial challenge to the validity of the San Jose ordinance

upon a passage in this court‘s decision in San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at

page 671. CBIA characterizes this portion of the San Remo Hotel decision as

resting upon an application of the unconstitutional conditions doctrine, but we

have demonstrated that doctrine is not applicable here because the ordinance does

not effect an exaction. We note, however, that the passage in question in San

Remo Hotel did not itself refer to that doctrine and the Court of Appeal decision in

City of Patterson, supra, 171 Cal.App.4th 886, upon which CBIA also relies, did

not analyze the passage in San Remo Hotel as an aspect of the unconstitutional

conditions doctrine. Accordingly, notwithstanding our rejection of CBIA‘s

unconstitutional conditions claim, we shall consider whether the passage in San

Remo Hotel upon which CBIA relies should properly be interpreted as applicable

to the challenged inclusionary housing ordinance.

CBIA proffers its argument in the face of the holding of the Court of

Appeal in City of Napa, supra, 90 Cal.App.4th 188, a case involving a facial

constitutional challenge to an inclusionary housing ordinance very similar to the

San Jose ordinance at issue here. There, the Court of Appeal held that the

ordinance was properly evaluated pursuant to the ordinary standard of review

generally applicable to land use regulations. Applying that standard, the City of

43

Napa court held that the challenged inclusionary housing ordinance was

constitutionally valid. (90 Cal.App.4th at pp. 195-197.)17

CBIA contends, however, that this court‘s decision in San Remo Hotel,

supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, which was decided after City of Napa, supra, 90

Cal.App.4th 188, should be interpreted to limit inclusionary housing requirements

only to those that are reasonably related to the adverse impacts that are caused by

or attributable to the proposed developments that are subject to the ordinance — in

effect, to requirements that satisfy something similar to the Nollan/Dolan test.

In San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, the land use restriction at issue

was a legislatively adopted ordinance aimed at preserving the amount of existing

long-term rental housing units in the city. The ordinance required any property

owner who proposed to convert existing long-term rental units to short-term

tourist units either to provide a comparable number of long-term rental units at

another location or to pay an in lieu fee into a fund dedicated exclusively to the

acquisition or construction of long-term rental units in the city. Evaluating the


17

At the time of the City of Napa decision, the controlling United States

Supreme Court decision provided that a land use regulation ―effects a taking if the
ordinance does not substantially advance legitimate state interests . . . .‖ (Agins v.
Tiburon
(1980) 447 U.S. 255, 260.) The City of Napa decision applied that
standard in upholding the inclusionary housing ordinance. Three years later, in
Lingle, supra, 544 U.S. 528, the federal high court held that the ―substantially
advance‖ standard set out in Agins is not an appropriate standard for determining
when a taking of property has occurred, and instead that the categorical and
regulatory taking categories described in Penn Central, supra, 438 U.S. 104,
constitute the appropriate taking standards. (Lingle, supra, 544 U.S. at pp. 540-
545.) After Lingle, the California Court of Appeal, in Action Apartment Assn. v.
City of Santa Monica
(2008) 166 Cal.App.4th 456, 467-471, upheld the validity of
an inclusionary housing ordinance against a facial constitutional challenge,
rejecting the plaintiffs‘ claim that under Lingle the ordinance was subject to the
Nollan/Dolan standard of review.

44

validity of the in lieu fee that had been imposed on the property owner in that case,

this court held in San Remo Hotel that the challenged fee was valid because it was

reasonably related to mitigating the impact that the landowner‘s proposed

conversion would have on the preservation of long-term rental housing in the city.

(San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at pp. 672-679.)

CBIA relies on one passage in the San Remo Hotel opinion that it asserts

indicates the conditions or requirements imposed by San Jose‘s inclusionary

housing ordinance are valid solely if they bear a reasonable relationship to the

deleterious public impacts attributable to the developments that are subject to the

ordinance. As we explain, properly interpreted, the passage in San Remo Hotel

does not support CBIA‘s contention.

The passage in question in San Remo Hotel is contained in a paragraph

responding to and rejecting an argument, based upon a hypothetical ordinance,

that had been advanced by the plaintiffs in that case. In asserting that the

legislatively prescribed long-term rental replacement fee before the court in San

Remo Hotel should be evaluated under the Nollan/Dolan heightened scrutiny

standard, the plaintiffs in San Remo Hotel warned of ―the danger a local legislative

body will use such purported mitigation fees — unrelated to the impacts of

development — simply to fill its coffers‖ and hypothesized that ―absent careful

constitutional scrutiny a city could ‗put zoning up for sale‘ by, for example,

‗prohibit[ing] all development except for one-story single-family homes, but

offer[ing] a second story permit for $20,000, an apartment building permit for

$10,000 per unit, a commercial building permit for $50,000 per floor, and so

forth.‘ ‖ (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at p. 670.)

In response to the plaintiffs‘ argument, the opinion in San Remo Hotel first

declined ―to extend heightened takings scrutiny to all development fees‖ and

instead adhered to the distinction drawn in earlier decisions of this court ―between

45

ad hoc exactions and legislatively mandated, formulaic mitigation fees.‖ (San

Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at pp. 670-671, citing Ehrlich, supra, 12 Cal.4th

854, Landgate, Inc. v. California Coastal Com. (1998) 17 Cal.4th 1006, and Santa

Monica Beach, supra, 19 Cal.4th 952.) The opinion explained: ―While

legislatively mandated fees do present some danger of improper leveraging, such

generally applicable legislation is subject to the ordinary restraints of the

democratic political process. A city council that charged extortionate fees for all

property development, unjustified by mitigation needs, would likely face

widespread and well-financed opposition at the next election. Ad hoc individual

monetary exactions deserve special scrutiny mainly because, affecting fewer

citizens and evading systematic assessment, they are more likely to escape such

political controls.‖ (San Remo Hotel, supra, at p. 671.)

The following paragraph in San Remo Hotel then set forth the court‘s

response to the plaintiffs‘ hypothetical: ―Nor are plaintiffs correct that, without

Nollan/Dolan/Ehrlich scrutiny, legislatively imposed development mitigation fees

are subject to no meaningful means-ends review. As a matter of both statutory

and constitutional law, such fees must bear a reasonable relationship, in both

intended use and amount, to the deleterious public impact of the development.

(Gov. Code, § 66001; Ehrlich, supra, 12 Cal.4th at pp. 865, 867 (plur. opn. of

Arabian, J.); id. at p. 897 (conc. opn. of Mosk, J.); Associated Home Builders etc.,

Inc. v. City of Walnut Creek (1971) 4 Cal.3d 633, 640.) Plaintiffs‘ hypothetical

city could only ‗put [its] zoning up for sale‘ in the manner imagined if the ‗prices‘

charged, and the intended use of the proceeds, bore a reasonable relationship to the

impacts of the various development intensity levels on public resources and

interests. While the relationship between means and ends need not be so close or

so thoroughly established for legislatively imposed fees as for ad hoc fees subject

to Ehrlich, the arbitrary and extortionate use of purported mitigation fees, even

46

where legislatively mandated, will not pass constitutional muster.‖ (San Remo

Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at p. 671, italics added.)

CBIA contends that the italicized sentence just quoted should be interpreted

to mean that the conditions imposed by the San Jose ordinance — requiring

developments of 20 or more units to make 15 percent of their on-site for-sale units

available for sale at affordable housing prices — would be valid only if those

requirements ―bear a reasonable relationship, in both intended use and amount, to

the deleterious public impact of the development.‖ (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27

Cal.4th at p. 671.) For several reasons, we conclude that CBIA‘s contention lacks

merit.

First, there is no indication that the passage in San Remo Hotel was

intended to apply to permit conditions, like the price controls imposed by the

challenged inclusionary housing ordinance, that regulate or place limits upon the

use of a property owner‘s property, rather than solely to conditions that require an

applicant to pay a monetary fee as a condition of obtaining a permit. The language

of the passage itself speaks specifically of ―fees,‖ not to conditions limiting the use

of property, and, as noted, the passage in San Remo Hotel was a direct response to

the concern expressed by the plaintiffs in that case that a permitting authority

would ―use such purported mitigation fees — unrelated to the impacts of

development — simply to fill its coffers.‖ (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at

p. 670.) In light of ―the special vulnerability of land use permit applicants to

extortionate demands for money‖ (Koontz, supra, 570 U.S. at p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d

at p. 717]), the passage is reasonably understood as applying to permit conditions

that require the payment of monetary fees.

Second, as we explain, a close reading of the entire paragraph containing

the italicized sentence discloses that the paragraph is explicitly addressed and

applies only to ―development mitigation fees‖ (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th

47

at p. 671, italics added) — that is, to fees whose purpose is to mitigate the effects

or impacts of the developments on which the fee is imposed — and does not

purport to apply to price controls or other land use restrictions that serve a broader

constitutionally permissible purpose or purposes unrelated to the impact of the

proposed development.

To begin, the initial sentence of the paragraph is explicitly limited to

―legislatively imposed development mitigation fees . . . .‖ (San Remo Hotel,

supra, 27 Cal.4th at p. 671, italics added.) Next, the term ―fee‖ as used in the

statute cited after the second sentence of the passage — Government Code section

66001, a key provision of California‘s Mitigation Fee Act — is statutorily defined

to mean ―a monetary exaction . . . that is charged by a local agency to the

applicant in connection with approval of a development project for the purpose of

defraying all or a portion of the cost of public facilities related to the development

project . . . .‖ (Gov. Code, § 66000, subd. (b), italics added.) The term ―fee‖ does

not purport to encompass use restrictions, and certainly not use restrictions that are

imposed for a different purpose. Further, the portions of the plurality and

concurring opinion in Ehrlich, supra, 12 Cal.4th at pages 865, 867, 895, and of the

majority opinion in Associated Home Builders, supra, 4 Cal.3d at page 640, to

which this paragraph in San Remo Hotel refers, similarly all involved development

mitigation fees whose purpose was to mitigate the effects of the proposed

developments, not use restrictions that were designed to serve other purposes.

Finally, the concluding sentence of the paragraph again refers explicitly to

―purported mitigation fees‖ (italics added), not to other types of permit conditions.

Viewed in isolation, the third sentence of the paragraph — referring to the

plaintiffs‘ suggestion that a hypothetical city might put up its zoning for sale —

could conceivably be read broadly to refer to any type of development fee.

However, when viewed in the context of the paragraph as a whole, and

48

particularly having in mind the paragraph‘s focus on a ―meaningful means-end

review‖ (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at p. 671), it appears clear that the

entire paragraph applies only to development mitigation fees ― and not to price

controls or other land use conditions or requirements (i.e., ―means‖) that are

imposed on proposed developments for a constitutionally permissible purpose

(i.e., ―end‖) other than mitigating the impact of the proposed development.

Nothing in San Remo Hotel purported to repudiate existing authority such as the

decision in City of Napa, supra, 90 Cal.App.4th 188, applying ordinary judicial

standards of review to land use regulations of the type involved in the present

case.18

In San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, the long-term rental unit

replacement requirement (and the related in-lieu fee) that was at issue was

explicitly intended to mitigate the adverse effect that a proposed conversion of

long-term rental units into tourist units would have on the city‘s stock of long-term

rental units. (Id. at p. 650.) Thus, the court‘s means-end analysis in that case was

understandably and properly focused upon whether the fee was reasonably related

to mitigating the impact of the proposed conversion. In the present case, as well,

one of the purposes of the challenged ordinance is to alleviate the impacts that

18

In stating that ―[a]s a matter of both statutory and constitutional law,

[legislatively imposed development mitigation] fees must bear a reasonable
relationship, in both intended use and amount, to the deleterious public impact of
the development‖ (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at p. 671), the opinion in
San Remo Hotel did not indicate whether the ―constitutional law‖ to which the
passage refers was a reference to due process or takings principles. Because the
ordinance in this case does not impose a development mitigation fee, we have no
occasion to explore that jurisprudential question, or to discuss how the constraints
imposed on legislatively prescribed development mitigation fees by the federal or
state Constitution compare with the constraints imposed by the Mitigation Fee
Act.

49

proposed market-rate residential development would have on the city‘s affordable

housing needs.19

Here, however, the ordinance makes clear that its purpose goes beyond

mitigating the impacts attributable to the proposed developments that are subject

to the ordinance. The San Jose ordinance is additionally aimed at a number of

distinct but nonetheless important and constitutionally permissible public

purposes, namely (1) to increase the amount of affordable housing in San Jose so

that the municipality can meet its responsibility of providing an adequate supply of

housing for individuals and families at all income levels and, at the same time,

(2) to assure that new affordable housing is distributed throughout the city in

economically diverse developments, avoiding the problems and detrimental effects

that municipalities have experienced in the past when low income housing is

relegated to separate, isolated locations within the community. Like other zoning

or land use regulations that are intended to shape and enhance the character and

quality of life of the community as a whole, San Jose‘s inclusionary housing

ordinance is intended to advance purposes beyond mitigating the impacts or

effects that are attributable to a particular development or project and instead ―to


19

As noted above (ante, p. 13), the ordinance identifies two distinct adverse

impacts that new market rate residential developments have upon the city‘s
existing affordable housing problem. First, new market rate housing
developments without affordable units use a portion of the limited existing land in
the city that is available for affordable housing and drive up the price of the
remaining land, reducing the opportunities for the construction of affordable
housing. Second, new residents of market rate housing create a demand for new
employees to service the needs of the new residents, and many of the needed new
employees (for example, teachers, transportation workers, etc.) will earn incomes
that are not adequate for market rate housing in the city. As a result, new market
rate housing exacerbates the city‘s affordable housing problem.


50

produce a widespread public benefit‖ (Penn Central, supra, 438 U.S. at p. 134,

fn. 30) that inures generally to the municipality as a whole, providing such

benefits to residents of new market-rate housing as well as to the other residents of

the community.

When a municipality enacts a broad zoning law that designates different

areas of the community for single-family housing, multiunit residences, and

commercial ventures, the validity of the law does not depend upon a judicial

means-end determination that focuses exclusively on the restrictions‘ relationship

to the adverse impact that would result from an alternative use of a particular

parcel or a particular proposed project. (See, e.g., Lingle, supra, 544 U.S. at

pp. 544-545; Penn Central, supra, 438 U.S. at pp. 133-135; HFH, Ltd. v. Superior

Court, supra, 15 Cal.3d at pp. 520-521.) Similarly, when a municipality enacts a

broad inclusionary housing ordinance to increase the amount of affordable housing

in the community and to disperse new affordable housing in economically diverse

projects throughout the community, the validity of the ordinance does not depend

upon a showing that the restrictions are reasonably related to the impact of a

particular development to which the ordinance applies. Rather, the restrictions

must be reasonably related to the broad general welfare purposes for which the

ordinance was enacted.

Unlike the decision in San Remo Hotel, in which we addressed a

development fee that was intended solely to mitigate the adverse effect of the

proposed conversion of long-term rental units to tourist units, in this court‘s earlier

decision in Ehrlich, supra, 12 Cal.4th 854, we had occasion to consider, among

other issues, the validity of a land use permit condition or requirement that was

intended, like the affordable housing condition at issue here, to serve a

constitutionally permissible public purpose other than mitigating the impact of the

proposed development project. For this reason, the Ehrlich decision provides

51

useful guidance in ascertaining the standard under which the validity of the San

Jose inclusionary housing ordinance is properly evaluated.

In Ehrlich, supra, 12 Cal.4th 854, the developer challenged the validity of

two different types of development conditions that the defendant city had imposed

as a condition of the plaintiff‘s proposed development: (1) a recreational-facility

replacement fee and (2) a public art requirement. The court in Ehrlich first held

that the ad hoc recreational-facility replacement fee that had been imposed in that

case should properly be evaluated under the Nollan/Dolan standard (Ehrlich,

supra, at pp. 874-881 (plur. opn. of Arabian, J.); id. at pp. 899-901 (conc. opn. of

Mosk, J.)), and, as such, the amount of the fee was required to be roughly

proportional to the adverse public impact attributable to the loss of property

reserved for private recreational use that would result from the developer‘s

proposed project. (Id. at pp. 882-885 (plur. opn. of Arabian, J.); id. at pp. 901-902

(conc. opn. of Mosk, J.).) Applying the Nollan/Dolan standard, the court in

Ehrlich concluded that the record was insufficient to support the amount of the

recreational-facility replacement fee that had been imposed in that case. (Id. at

pp. 884-885 (plur. opn. of Arabian, J.); id. at pp. 901-902 (conc. opn. of

Mosk, J.).)

By contrast, with respect to the public art condition — which required the

developer either (1) to pay into the city art fund a fee equal to 1 percent of the total

building valuation, or (2) to contribute an approved work of public art of an

equivalent value that could be placed on site or donated to the city for placement

elsewhere — the court in Ehrlich did not evaluate the validity of the condition by

asking whether or not the amount of the required fee or value of the work of art

was reasonably related to the adverse impact that the proposed development would

have on the existing state of public art in the city. The purpose of the public art

requirement in question was not to replace existing public art that would be

52

eliminated by a proposed project or to mitigate any adverse impact on the amount

of public art in the community that would result from the proposed development.

Instead, the purpose of the public art requirement was to increase the works of

public art that are present in the community for the general benefit of the

community as a whole, by requiring all future large development projects to

provide some public art or to pay an in lieu fee to be used for the acquisition of

public art in another location. Given this purpose, application of a legal test that

would limit all public art requirements only to those requirements that mitigate the

impact of a proposed project would have resulted in the invalidation of the

challenged condition. Instead, in Ehrlich this court upheld the validity of the

public art requirement (including the related in lieu public art fee) upon finding

that the requirement (and related in lieu fee) was reasonably related to the

constitutionally legitimate public purpose of increasing the amount of publicly

accessible works of art for the benefit of the community and the public as a whole.

(Ehrlich, supra, 12 Cal.4th at pp. 885-886 (plur. opn. of Arabian, J.); id. at p. 902

(conc. opn. of Mosk, J.); id. at p. 907 (conc. & dis. opn. of Kennard, J.); id. at

p. 912 (conc. & dis. opn. of Werdegar, J.).)

CBIA argues that this court‘s decision upholding the validity of the public

art condition in Ehrlich, supra, 12 Cal.4th 854, is not applicable to the affordable

housing requirement at issue here because, unlike the public art requirement, the

affordable housing requirement challenged in this case is not an ―aesthetic

control.‖ CBIA, however, fails to identify a persuasive constitutional or other

legal justification for limiting our holding in Ehrlich to development restrictions

that constitute ―aesthetic controls.‖ CBIA maintains that the requirement in

Ehrlich that a developer provide public art or pay an in lieu fee was more like

ordinary land use restrictions commonly contained in zoning or building codes

than the price controls imposed by San Jose‘s inclusionary housing ordinance.

53

Whether or not that is true, as already explained, it is well established that price

controls are a constitutionally permissible form of regulation with regard to real

property as well as to other types of property or services. (See, ante, pp. 35-36.)

Accordingly, just as it would be permissible for a municipality to attempt to

increase the amount of affordable housing in the community and to promote

economically diverse developments by requiring all new residential developments

to include a specified percentage of studio, one-bedroom, or small-square-footage

units, there is no reason why a municipality may not alternatively attempt to

achieve those same objectives by requiring new developments to set aside a

percentage of its proposed units for sale at a price that is affordable to moderate or

low income households. So long as the price controls are not confiscatory and do

not constitute a regulatory taking, there is no reason such price controls should not

be evaluated under the same standard applicable to the public art requirement in

Ehrlich and other land use measures that are not subject to the Nollan/Dolan test,

namely, that such regulations must be reasonably related to a constitutionally

permissible public purpose.

Finally, the fact that the San Jose ordinance provides a developer with the

option of paying an in lieu fee instead of providing the required on-site affordable

housing units does not provide a basis for applying the test advocated by CBIA to

the ordinance‘s affordable housing requirements as a whole. No developer is

required to pay the in lieu fee and may always opt to satisfy the ordinance by

providing on-site affordable housing units. Because an in lieu fee option is often

included in inclusionary housing ordinances to satisfy the demands of developers

who seek the flexibility that an in lieu fee alternative affords, CBIA cannot

properly rely upon the inclusion of such an option as a basis for challenging the

validity of the San Jose inclusionary housing ordinance as a whole. (Accord,

Koontz, supra, 570 U.S. at p. __ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 712] [―We agree with

54

respondent that, so long as a permitting authority offers the landowner at least one

alternative that would satisfy Nollan and Dolan, the landowner has not been

subjected to an unconstitutional condition.‖].)

Moreover, as we have explained above, the validity of the ordinance‘s

requirement that at least 15 percent of a development‘s for-sale units be affordable

to moderate or low income households does not depend on an assessment of the

impact that the development itself will have on the municipality‘s affordable

housing situation. Consequently, the validity of the in lieu fee — which is an

alternative to the on-site affordable housing requirement — logically cannot

depend on whether the amount of the in lieu fee is reasonably related to the

development‘s impact on the city‘s affordable housing need.

In sum, we conclude that the requirements of the inclusionary housing

ordinance at issue here do not conflict with the passage in San Remo Hotel upon

which CBIA relies. Accordingly, there is no merit to CBIA‘s contention that,

under San Remo Hotel, the ordinance is invalid on its face because the city failed

to show that the ordinance‘s inclusionary housing requirements are reasonably

related to the impact on affordable housing attributable to such developments.20


20

In Holmdel Builders Assn. v. Township of Holmdel (N.J. 1990) 583 A.2d

277, the New Jersey Supreme Court reached a similar conclusion in upholding the
validity of municipal ordinances that imposed an affordable-housing fee on new
development that was to be used to satisfy the municipality‘s obligation to provide
its ―fair share‖ of low and moderate income housing as set forth in earlier New
Jersey Supreme Court decisions. (See Southern Burlington County NAACP v.
Mount Laurel Township
(N.J. 1975) 336 A.2d 713 Southern Burlington County
NAACP v. Mount Laurel Township
(N.J. 1983) 456 A.2d 390.)


Rejecting the claim that the affordable-housing fees imposed by such an

ordinance require ―a but-for causal connection or direct consequential relationship
between the private activity that gives rise to the exaction and the public activity to
which it is applied‖ (Holmdel Builders Assn., supra, 583 A.2d at p. 288), the court
held that ―[i]nclusionary zoning through the imposition of development fees is


(footnote continued on next page)

55

We acknowledge that in City of Patterson, supra, 171 Cal.App.4th 886, a

panel of the Court of Appeal reached a contrary conclusion regarding the

applicability of the passage in San Remo Hotel to an inclusionary housing

ordinance. But, as we explain, for a number of reasons we conclude that the City

of Patterson decision was incorrect in this respect.

In City of Patterson, supra, 171 Cal.App.4th 886, the applicable ordinance

gave a developer the option of building affordable housing units or paying an in

lieu fee (id. at p. 890), but the appellate court decision in that case focused solely

on the question of the validity of the in lieu fee viewed in isolation. (See id. at

pp. 894-899.) At the time the development in question was first approved by the

city, the in lieu affordable-housing fee required by the applicable ordinance was

set at $734 per affordable housing unit. Three years later, however, when the

developer applied for the required building permit, the applicable in lieu fee had

increased (as a result of a very substantial reduction in the federal and state

affordable housing subsidies available to the city) to $20,946 per affordable unit.

The development agreement that had been entered into by the developer explicitly

specified that the applicable in lieu fee would be the fee in effect at the time the

building permit was issued, and further noted that the city was then in the process

of preparing an updated affordable-housing fee. In the development agreement,

the developer agreed to be bound by the revised fee schedule ― ‗provid[ed] the

same is reasonably justified.‘ ‖ (Id. at p. 895.) In bringing the City of Patterson


(footnote continued from previous page)

permissible because such fees are conducive to the creation of a realistic
opportunity for the development of affordable housing; development fees are the
functional equivalent of mandatory set-asides; and it is fair and reasonable to
impose such fee requirements on private developers when they possess, enjoy, and
consume land, which constitutes the primary resource for housing.‖ (Ibid.)

56

lawsuit, the developer contended that the increased in lieu fee was not ―reasonably

justified‖ within the meaning of the agreement.

In addressing the proper interpretation of the term ―reasonably justified‖ as

used in the development agreement, the Court of Appeal in City of Patterson,

supra, 171 Cal.App.4th 886, initially concluded that the term should be interpreted

to mean ―that any increase in the affordable housing in lieu fee would conform to

existing law‖ (id. at p. 896), or, in other words, that the revised in lieu fee imposed

by the city would be permissible so long as the amount of the revised fee would

not violate the established legal principles governing a city‘s in lieu affordable-

housing fee. (Ibid.)

Thereafter, in analyzing that issue, the City of Patterson court concluded

that the requirements set forth in the passage in San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th

643, discussed above, constituted the applicable legal test governing the validity of

the in lieu housing fee at issue in that case. In reaching this conclusion, the City of

Patterson court reasoned: ―Upon examination, it appears that the affordable

housing in-lieu fee challenged here is not substantively different from the

replacement in-lieu fee considered in San Remo. Both are formulaic, legislatively

mandated fees imposed as conditions to developing property, not discretionary ad

hoc exactions. [Citation.] We conclude, for this reason, that the level of

constitutional scrutiny applied by the court in San Remo must be applied to City‘s

affordable housing in-lieu fee and is one of the legal requirements incorporated

into the Development Agreement.‖ (City of Patterson, supra, 171 Cal.App.4th at

p. 898.) The City of Patterson court noted that the city ―argues for no different

test.‖ (Ibid.) Applying the San Remo Hotel test, the City of Patterson court found

that because nothing in the record ―demonstrates or implies the increased fee was

reasonably related to the need for affordable housing associated with the project‖

57

(City of Patterson, at p. 899), the increased fee was not reasonably justified within

the meaning of the development agreement.

Although the affordable-housing in lieu fee at issue in City of Patterson,

supra, 171 Cal.App.4th 886, and the long-term rental replacement fee at issue in

San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, shared the characteristics noted by the

Court of Appeal in City of Patterson (both were formulaic, legislatively mandated

fees), the court in City of Patterson overlooked a critical difference between the

two. Unlike the long-term rental replacement in lieu fee in San Remo Hotel, the

affordable-housing in lieu fee in City of Patterson was not imposed for the

purpose of mitigating an adverse effect that was caused by the developer but was

imposed to further the very different public purpose of increasing the stock of

affordable housing in the city to meet the need for affordable housing as

determined by the relevant county council of governments. (171 Cal.App.4th at

p. 892.) In City of Patterson, the defendant city apparently did not raise this point

or object to the application of the San Remo Hotel test, and the City of Patterson

court did not take into account this difference from the San Remo Hotel case on its

own. Moreover, the City of Patterson decision did not evaluate the ordinance‘s

affordable housing condition as a whole, and, in particular, failed to consider how

the fact that the ordinance afforded the developer the option of complying with the

condition by providing affordable housing units within the development affected

the validity of the alternative methods of complying with the ordinance‘s

affordable housing condition, including the optional in lieu fee.

For the reasons discussed above, we disapprove the decision in Building

Industry Assn. of Central California v. City of Patterson, supra, 171 Cal.App.4th

886, to the extent it indicates that the conditions imposed by an inclusionary

zoning ordinance are valid only if they are reasonably related to the need for

affordable housing attributable to the projects to which the ordinance applies. At

58

the same time, because the question is not before us, we express no opinion

regarding the validity of the amount of the particular in lieu fee at issue in City of

Patterson or of the methodology utilized in arriving at that fee. (See id. at

pp. 891-893.)


VI. Is this court’s recent decision in Sterling Park, supra, 57 Cal.4th


1193, inconsistent with the conclusions reached above?

Finally, CBIA asserts that this court‘s recent decision in Sterling Park,

supra, 57 Cal.4th 1193, supports its contention that the test set forth in San Remo

Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, applies to the affordable housing requirement of the

San Jose inclusionary housing ordinance at issue here. As we explain, the legal

issue that was presented and decided in Sterling Park bears no relationship to the

issue presented here, and we conclude the Sterling Park decision does not support

CBIA‘s position in this case.

In Sterling Park, supra, 57 Cal.4th 1193, the issue before this court was

which of two statutes of limitation applied to the lawsuit at issue in that case. One

of the potentially applicable statutes of limitation — Government Code section

66499.37, a part of the Subdivision Map Act — was a general statute of

limitations requiring lawsuits challenging the validity of conditions attached to the

approval of a tentative or final map to be filed ―within 90 days after the date of the

decision‖ attaching the condition. The other potentially applicable statute of

limitations — Government Code section 66020, a part of the Mitigation Fee Act

— permitted a developer to protest ―the imposition of any fees, dedications,

reservations, or other exactions‖ by ―[t]endering any required payment in full‖

under protest and thereafter to file a lawsuit within 180 days after receiving notice

of the required payment.

The underlying facts in Sterling Park, supra, 57 Cal.4th 1193, arose out of

an inclusionary housing ordinance adopted by the City of Palo Alto that required

59

housing projects involving the development of five or more acres to provide at

least 20 percent of all units as affordable units or alternatively to pay an in lieu fee

equal to 10 percent of the actual sales price or fair market price of the market rate

units. The plaintiff developer, who wished to construct 96 residential

condominiums on 6.5 acres of land in the city, entered into a development

agreement with the city in which the developer agreed to provide 10 below market

rate units and to pay an in lieu fee equal to 5.3488 percent of the actual selling

price or fair market value of the market rate units. More than a year after the

development agreement had been entered into and the developer‘s application for

a final subdivision map had been approved, at a time when construction of the new

units was nearing completion, the city demanded compliance with the below

market rate conditions set forth in the development agreement. At that juncture,

the developer, claiming that the prior agreement had been signed under duress and

that the below market rate requirements imposed by the ordinance were invalid,

submitted ―a notice of protest‖ with the city. When the city failed to respond to

the protest, the developer filed the lawsuit at issue in Sterling Park, seeking a

declaration that the below-market rate requirements were invalid and praying for

equitable relief.

In the trial court proceedings in Sterling Park, the city moved for summary

judgment on the ground that the developer‘s lawsuit was untimely, contending that

the applicable limitations period was that set out in Government Code section

66499.37, and that under that provision the lawsuit had been filed too late. The

trial court agreed with the city and granted summary judgment in the city‘s favor;

on appeal, the Court of Appeal affirmed, holding that the provisions of

Government Code section 66020, relied upon by the developer, were not

applicable and that the action was untimely under section 66499.37. We granted

review to determine which statute of limitations — section 66020 or section

60

66499.37 — governed the lawsuit in question. (Sterling Park, supra, 57 Cal.4th at

p. 1197.)

In Sterling Park we concluded that the statute of limitations provisions of

Government Code section 66020 (part of the Mitigation Fee Act) should properly

be interpreted to apply to the affordable housing requirements imposed by the Palo

Alto inclusionary housing ordinance. In reaching that conclusion, we relied

heavily on the background and legislative purpose of the protest and statute of

limitations provisions of section 66020. We noted that section 66020 was enacted

to permit a developer who wished to challenge a fee that was a condition of

development to pay the contested fee under protest and to continue with the

construction of the development while its legal challenge to the fee went forward.

This statutory procedure embodied in section 66020 replaced the prior procedural

rule that required a developer either (1) to delay any construction until its legal

challenge to a development condition or fee was finally resolved or (2) to go

forward with the construction and be treated as having waived any challenge to the

contested requirement. (Sterling Park, supra, 57 Cal.4th at p. 1200.)

In finding the provisions of Government Code section 66020 applicable to

the affordable housing requirement at issue in that case, we explained: ―The

procedure established in section 66020, which permits a developer to pay or

otherwise ensure performance of the exactions, and then challenge the exactions

while proceeding with the project, makes sense regarding monetary exactions. By

the nature of things, some conditions a local entity might impose on a developer,

like a limit on the number of units [citation], cannot be challenged while the

project is being built. Obviously, one cannot build a project now and litigate later

how many units the project can contain — or how large each unit can be, or the

validity of other use restrictions a local entity might impose. But the validity of

monetary exactions, or requirements that the developer later set aside a certain

61

number of units to be sold below market value, can be litigated while the project is

being built. In the former situation — where the nature of the project must be

decided before construction — it makes sense to have tight time limits to

minimize the delay. In the latter situation — where the project can be built while

litigating the validity of fees or other exactions — it makes sense to allow payment

under protest followed by a challenge and somewhat less stringent time limits.‖

(Sterling Park, supra, 57 Cal.4th at pp. 1206-1207.)

In the course of the Sterling Park opinion, we rejected the city‘s contention

that the requirements of its inclusionary housing ordinance should not be

considered ―exactions‖ as that term is used in Government Code section 66020.

We stated in this regard: ―The below market rate program is different from a land

use regulation of the type at issue in Fogarty [v. City of Chico (2007) 148

Cal.App.4th 537] (a limit on the number of units that can be built); instead, it is

similar to a fee, dedication, or reservation under section 66020. The program

offers developers two options, either of which, by itself, would constitute an

exaction. The imposition of the in-lieu fees is certainly similar to a fee.

Moreover, the requirement that the developer sell units below market rate,

including the City‘s reservation of an option to purchase the below market rate

units, is similar to a fee, dedication, or reservation. It may be, as the City argues,

that under traditional property law, an option to purchase creates no estate in the

land. But a purchase option is a sufficiently strong interest in the property to

require compensation if the government takes it in eminent domain. [Citation.]

Compelling the developer to give the City a purchase option is an exaction under

section 66020. Because of this conclusion, we need not decide whether forcing

the developer to sell some units below market value, by itself, would constitute an

exaction under section 66020.‖ (Sterling Park, supra, 57 Cal.4th at p. 1207.)

62

As the quoted passage indicates, our decision in Sterling Park, supra, 57

Cal.4th 1193, left open the question whether the protest procedure and statute of

limitations set forth in Government Code section 66020 would apply to the

affordable housing requirements of all inclusionary housing ordinances, including

inclusionary housing ordinances, like the San Jose ordinance at issue here, that do

not require the developer to give the city an option to purchase the affordable

housing units the developer is obligated to provide. (See, ante, p. 40, & fn. 15.)

But whether or not the affordable housing requirements of the San Jose ordinance

should be considered ―exactions‖ as that term is used in Government Code section

66020, and thus are subject to the procedural protest and statute of limitations

provisions of that statute — an issue we need not and do not decide — it is clear

that our decision in Sterling Park did not address or intend to express any view

whatsoever with regard to the legal test that applies in evaluating the substantive

validity of the affordable housing requirements imposed by an inclusionary

housing ordinance. The opinion in Sterling Park focused exclusively on the

procedural issue presented in that case and made no mention of the passage in San

Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th 643, or any other substantive legal test. Nothing in

Sterling Park supports CBIA‘s claim that the challenged San Jose ordinance is

subject to a judicial standard of review different from that traditionally applied to

other legislatively mandated land use development requirements.

63





VII. Conclusion

As noted at the outset of this opinion, for many decades California statutes

and judicial decisions have recognized the critical need for more affordable

housing in this state. Over the years, a variety of means have been advanced and

undertaken to address this challenging need. We emphasize that the legal question

before our court in this case is not the wisdom or efficacy of the particular tool or

method that the City of San Jose has adopted, but simply whether, as the Court of

Appeal held, the San Jose ordinance is subject to the ordinary standard of judicial

review to which legislative land use regulations have traditionally been subjected.

For the reasons discussed above, the judgment of the Court of Appeal is

affirmed.

CANTIL-SAKAUYE, C. J.

WE CONCUR:

WERDEGAR, J.
CORRIGAN, J.
LIU, J.
CUÉLLAR, J.
KRUGER, J.


64












CONCURRING OPINION BY WERDEGAR, J.




I concur fully in the majority opinion, which I have signed. I write

separately to speak to the current status and meaning of the ―reasonable

relationship‖ constitutional standard set out in San Remo Hotel v. City and County

of San Francisco (2002) 27 Cal.4th 643 (San Remo Hotel), a decision I authored

for the court.

As explained in the majority opinion (maj. opn., ante, at pp. 45–47), in San

Remo Hotel we addressed the constitutional standard for reviewing legislatively

prescribed, formulaic mitigation fees. We first determined such fees were not

subject to the heightened means-ends scrutiny established under the takings clause

in Nollan v. California Coastal Commission (1987) 483 U.S. 825 (Nollan) and

Dolan v. City of Tigard (1994) 512 U.S. 374 (Dolan) for ad hoc, discretionary

exactions. (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at pp. 665–671.) In reaching this

conclusion, we rejected the plaintiffs‘ contention that a lack of heightened scrutiny

would mean legislatively imposed development mitigation fees would not be

subject to meaningful means-ends review, stating: ―As a matter of both statutory

and constitutional law, such fees must bear a reasonable relationship, in both

intended use and amount, to the deleterious public impact of the development. . . .

While the relationship between means and ends need not be so close or so

thoroughly established for legislatively imposed fees as for ad hoc fees subject to

Ehrlich, the arbitrary and extortionate use of purported mitigation fees, even

where legislatively mandated, will not pass constitutional muster.‖ (San Remo

1



Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at p. 671, citing Ehrlich v. City of Culver City (1996) 12

Cal.4th 854 (Ehrlich) [applying Nollan and Dolan to ad hoc fees].) Applying the

constitutional standard, we then concluded the challenged housing replacement fee

bore a reasonable relationship to the loss of housing caused by conversion of hotel

rooms from residential to tourist use. (San Remo Hotel, at p. 673.)

As the majority opinion observes, the court in San Remo Hotel did not

specify whether the constitutional provision from which it drew the reasonable

relationship test for legislatively formulated development mitigation fees was the

due process clause, the takings clause, or both. (Maj. opn., ante, at p. 49, fn. 18.)

Because the ordinance at issue in this case does not impose a mitigation fee, the

court today has no occasion to address the constitutional derivation or exact

dimensions of this reasonable relationship standard. (Ibid.) For future cases,

however, it may be helpful to note a significant change in federal constitutional

law since San Remo Hotel‘s decision, a change that suggests the reasonable

relationship test for mitigation fees may be no more demanding than the

deferential standard applicable to ordinary land use regulations under the due

process clause. (See maj. opn., ante, at pp. 23–24 [land use regulation meets due

process limitations if it bears a reasonable relationship to the public welfare].)

At the time we decided San Remo Hotel, the United States Supreme Court‘s

takings doctrine held a land use regulation ―effects a taking if the ordinance does

not substantially advance legitimate state interests . . . .‖ (Agins v. Tiburon (1980)
447 U.S. 255, 260 (Agins).) After our decision, the high court in Lingle v.

Chevron U.S.A. Inc. (2005) 544 U.S. 528, 540–545 (Lingle) clarified that this

means-ends standard stated a due process principle, not a test for a regulatory

taking. But in the meantime, the Agins standard appears to have played a leading

role in San Remo Hotel‘s statement of a reasonable relationship standard for

legislatively formulated development mitigation fees.

In San Remo Hotel, we outlined the broad categories of recognized takings

claims, listing last the ―substantially advance‖ standard; we then introduced the

2



plaintiffs‘ claims as implicating ―the last-mentioned prong of the high court‘s

takings analysis.‖ (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at p. 665.) And as

decisional authority for the reasonable relationship test we applied to those claims,

we cited portions of the plurality opinion and of Justice Mosk‘s concurrence in

Ehrlich, both of which directly or indirectly invoked the Agins ―substantially

advance‖ takings test. (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th at p. 671; see Ehrlich,

supra, 12 Cal.4th at pp. 865–867, 870, fn. 7 (plur. opn.) [equating reasonable

relationship takings standard with Nollan/Dolan scrutiny and viewing latter as

derived from ― ‗substantially advance‘ ‖ test], 897 (conc. opn. of Mosk, J.)

[viewing reasonable relationship takings standard as closer to rational basis test

than to Nollan/Dolan scrutiny, but deriving it from Agins‘s means-ends takings

principle].)

San Remo Hotel‘s use of a means-ends analysis to evaluate the plaintiffs‘

takings claims was appropriate in light of the then-extant ―substantially advance‖

prong of federal takings law. But three years later, in Lingle, the high court

―correct[ed] course‖ (Lingle, supra, 544 U.S. at p. 548) and eliminated

means-ends analysis as a distinct prong of takings law. The court determined that

Agins‘s formula ―prescribes an inquiry in the nature of a due process, not a

takings, test, and that it has no proper place in our takings jurisprudence.‖ (Lingle,

at p. 540.) The court explained that Agins had drawn its standard from due

process cases, not takings ones, and that means-ends testing of this nature

belonged solely to due process analysis: ―The ‗substantially advances‘ formula

suggests a means-ends test: It asks, in essence, whether a regulation of private

property is effective in achieving some legitimate public purpose. An inquiry of

this nature has some logic in the context of a due process challenge, for a

regulation that fails to serve any legitimate governmental objective may be so

arbitrary or irrational that it runs afoul of the Due Process Clause. . . . But such a

test is not a valid method of discerning whether private property has been ‗taken‘

for purposes of the Fifth Amendment.‖ (Lingle, at p. 542.) The Lingle court

3



further explained that Nollan and Dolan, though they both quoted the Agins

formula, actually rested on the very different principle of ― ‗ ―unconstitutional

conditions.‖ ‘ ‖ (Lingle, at pp. 547-548; see maj. opn., ante, at pp. 25–27.)

Given the high court‘s abandonment of the idea that a regulation works a

taking of private property if it does not substantially advance a legitimate

government interest, how should our statement in San Remo Hotel—that

legislatively formulated mitigation fees must, as a constitutional as well as a

statutory matter, be reasonably related to the development‘s impacts—be

understood? Does San Remo Hotel state a takings test or a due process test?

Theoretically, one could argue Lingle makes no difference, as it addressed

federal constitutional law while the plaintiffs in San Remo Hotel brought their

challenge solely under the California Constitution. (San Remo Hotel, supra, 27

Cal.4th at p. 664.) But we observed in San Remo Hotel that the two Constitutions‘

takings clauses are, with some exceptions, generally construed congruently, and

we therefore analyzed the plaintiffs‘ takings claim ―under the relevant decisions of

both this court and the United States Supreme Court.‖ (San Remo Hotel, at p.

664.) Had Lingle already been decided, we would have considered it in our

analysis.

In light of Lingle, I believe, San Remo Hotel‘s reasonable relationship test

for legislatively formulated mitigation fees is best understood to state a due

process standard, not a takings one. As the Lingle court emphasized, regulatory

takings law is centrally concerned not with the ―fit‖ between a regulation and its

goals but with the burdens the regulation imposes on a property owner, both

absolutely and relative to others in the community. ―The owner of a property

subject to a regulation that effectively serves a legitimate state interest may be just

as singled out and just as burdened as the owner of a property subject to an

ineffective regulation. . . . Likewise, an ineffective regulation may not

significantly burden property rights at all, and it may distribute any burden broadly

and evenly among property owners.‖ (Lingle, supra, 544 U.S. at p. 543.) San

4



Remo Hotel‘s reasonable relationship test does not focus on the absolute or

relative burden of a mitigation fee, but on whether it is reasonably justified by the

legislative goal of mitigating development impacts. As such, it relates most

naturally not to whether private property has been taken but to whether the fee

regulation is ―so arbitrary or irrational that it runs afoul of the Due Process

Clause.‖ (Lingle, at p. 542.)

As explained in the majority opinion, in a due process challenge to police

power regulations, the burden of proof is on the party challenging the ordinance,

rather than on the government: the challenger must demonstrate that the measure

lacks a reasonable relationship to the public welfare. (Maj. opn., ante, at p. 23.) A

developer challenging a legislatively mandated mitigation fee under San Remo

Hotel would thus need to show the fee lacks a substantial relationship to the

deleterious impacts of, or public resource needs created by, the development. This

mode of means-ends scrutiny has been generally equated to the rational-basis

standard. (See Santa Monica Beach, Ltd. v. Superior Court (1999) 19 Cal.4th 952,

978–980 (conc. opn. of Kennard, J.).) Under this deferential form of analysis, for

the challenger to show that the city or other entity imposing a fee had not

undertaken individualized studies to determine the size of fee needed for

mitigating the impacts of each development presumably would not be enough. I

am unaware of any decisions suggesting a mitigation fee is arbitrary or irrational

merely because it is not demonstrably proportionate to individual development

impacts, so long as the fee schedule‘s overall scale and structure has a real and

substantial relationship to the public measures needed to accommodate and

mitigate the effects of the development. (See San Remo Hotel, supra, 27 Cal.4th

at p. 672 [reasonable relationship standard does not ―open to searching judicial

scrutiny the wisdom of myriad government economic regulations‖].)

5



Again, I concur without qualification in the majority opinion, which

appropriately refrains from addressing in detail issues that are not before us here.

I add the above discussion only as a potentially useful reference point for analysis

in any future case where the constitutionality of a legislatively mandated

development mitigation fee is at issue.













WERDEGAR, J.




6












CONCURRING OPINION BY CHIN, J.

I agree that the inclusionary housing ordinance at issue here is not an

exaction of property for takings purposes and thus is not subject to the test this

court established in San Remo Hotel v. City and County of San Francisco (2002)

27 Cal.4th 643. Instead, ―the ordinance falls within . . . municipalities‘ general

broad discretion to regulate the use of real property to serve the legitimate interests

of the general public and the community at large.‖ (Maj. opn., ante, at p. 32.) But

my reasons for upholding the ordinance are narrow.

The ordinance requires the developer to provide a certain number of units

that are more affordable, i.e., less expensive, than the unrestricted units

presumably will be. This requirement might cause the developer to make a

smaller profit on these affordable units than on other units, but so do many valid

zoning requirements. What the ordinance does not do, at least on a facial

challenge, is require the developer to provide subsidized housing.

The ordinance does not prohibit the developer from building the affordable

units in a less expensive way than the other units. It does restrict the ways the

developer can build the affordable units more cheaply than other units. As the

majority summarizes it, the ordinance requires that the affordable units ―have the

same quality of exterior design and comparable square footage and bedroom count

as market rate units.‖ (Maj. opn., ante, at p. 17.) But the ordinance also ―permits

1



some different ‗unit types‘ of affordable units (for example, in developments with

detached single-family market rate units, the affordable units may be attached

single-family units or may be placed on smaller lots than the market rate units)

[citation], and also allows the affordable units to have different, but functionally

equivalent, interior finishes, features, and amenities, compared with the market

rate units.‖ (Ibid.)

Thus, the ordinance leaves room for the developer to build the affordable

units more cheaply than the other units. Accordingly, it is not clear to me, and

certainly not on a facial challenge, that the developer could not turn a profit even

on the affordable units, although probably a smaller one than on the unrestricted

units. Because of this, I agree with the majority that the ordinance is a valid land

use regulation.

But an ordinance that did require the developer to provide subsidized

housing, for example, by requiring it to sell some units below cost, would present

an entirely different situation. Such an ordinance would appear to be an exaction,

and I question whether it could be upheld as simply a form of price control. (See,

e.g., maj. opn., ante, at pp 36-37.)

Providing affordable housing is a strong, perhaps even compelling,

governmental interest. But it is an interest of the government. Or, as the majority

puts it, it is an interest ―of the general public and the community at large.‖ (Maj.

opn., ante, at p. 32.) The community as a whole should bear the burden of

furthering this interest, not merely some segment of the community. ―All of us

must bear our fair share of the public costs of maintaining and improving the

communities in which we live and work. But the United States Constitution,

through the takings clause of the Fifth Amendment, protects us all from being

arbitrarily singled out and subjected to bearing a disproportionate share of these

2



costs.‖ (Ehrlich v. City of Culver City (1996) 12 Cal.4th 854, 912 (conc. & dis.

opn. of Kennard, J.).)

With this caveat, I join the majority in upholding the ordinance in question.

CHIN, J.

3



See last page for addresses and telephone numbers for counsel who argued in Supreme Court.

Name of Opinion California Building Industry Association v City of San Jose
__________________________________________________________________________________

Unpublished Opinion

Original Appeal
Original Proceeding
Review Granted
XXX 216 Cal.App.4th 1373
Rehearing Granted

__________________________________________________________________________________

Opinion No.
S212072
Date Filed: June 15, 2015
__________________________________________________________________________________

Court:
Superior
County: Santa Clara
Judge: Socrates Peter Manoukian

__________________________________________________________________________________

Counsel:

Berliner Cohen, Andrew L. Faber, Thomas P. Murphy; Richard Doyle, City Attorney, Nora Frimann,
Assistant City Attorney and Margo Laskowska, Deputy City Attorney, for Defendant and Appellant.

Burke, Williams & Sorensen and Thomas P. Brown for League of California Cities and California State
Association of Counties as Amici Curiae on behalf of Defendant and Appellant.

Kamala D. Harris, Attorney General, Edward C. DuMont, State Solicitor General, John A. Saurenman,
Assistant Attorney General, Janill L. Richards, Deptuy State Solicitor General, Daniel L. Siegel and
Christiana Tiedemann, Deputy Attorneys General, for Attorney General, as Amicus Curiae on behalf of
Defendant and Appellant.

Richard A. Rothschild, KeAndra Dodds and Navneet K. Grewal for National Housing Law Project, Public
Advocates, Public Counsel and Western Center on Law and Poverty as Amici Curiae on behalf of
Defendant and Appellant.

Michael Timothy Iglesias for Leo T. McCarthy Center for Public Service and the Common Good, Corey
Cook, Elizabeth S. Anderson, Peter Marcuse, Dr. Patrick Sharkey, Susan Eaton, Carolina K. Reid, Dr.
Mark Santow, Camille Z. Charles, Elizabeth J. Mueller, James A. Kushner, Rigel C. Oliveri, William P.
Quigley, David Rusk, Janis M. Breidenbach, Peter Dreier, J. Rosie Tighe, Victoria Basolo, Stephen
Menendian, John A. Powell, Tracy K‘Meyer, Philip Tegeler, James J. Kelly, Jr., Gregory D. Squires, Peter
W. Salsich, Jr., Florence Wagman Roisman, Nico Calavita, Gerald S. Dickinson, Thomas M. Shapiro, Dan
Immergluck, Myron Orfield, Jr., Timothy M. Mulvaney, George Lipsitz, Sarah Schindler, Michael P. Seng,
John Goering, Joe Feagin, Nancy Denton, Kathleen C. Engel, John Mollenkopf, Gary Dymski, Gary
Orfield, Mark L. Roark, Todd Swanstrom, William M. Wiecek and Susan D. Bennett as Amici Curiae on
behalf of Defendant and Appellant.

Fenwick & West, Ryan J. Marton, Sebastian E. Kaplan and Julia M. Kolibachuk for Silicon Valley
Leadership Group and Working Partnership USA as Amici Curiae on behalf of Defendant and Appellant.




1






Page 2 – S212072 – counsel continued

Counsel:

Law Foundation of Silicon Valley Public Interest Law Firm, Kyra Kazantzis, James F. Zahradka II, Melissa
A. Morris; The Public Interest Law Project California Affordable Housing Law Project, Michael Rawson;
Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati, Colleen Bal, Corina I. Cacovean; and L. David Nefouse for Interveners
and Appellants.

Sheppard, Mullin, Richter & Hampton, Rutan & Tucker, David P. Lanferman, James G. Higgins; Pacific
Legal Foundation, Damien M. Schiff, Anthony L. Francois; Nick Cammarota; and Paul Campos for
Plaintiff and Respondent.

Paul B. Campos for Building Industry Association of the Bay Area as Amicus Curiae on behalf of Plaintiff
and Respondent.

June Babiracki Barlow and Neil Kain for California Association of REALTORS as Amicus Curiae on
behalf of Plaintiff and Respondent.

Devala A. Janardan and Thomas J. Ward for National Association of Home Builders of as Amicus Curiae
on behalf of Plaintiff and Respondent.


2







Counsel who argued in Supreme Court (not intended for publication with opinion):

Andrew L. Faber
Berliner Cohen
Ten Almaden Boulevard, 11th Floor
San Jose, CA 95113-2233
(408) 286-5800

Melissa A. Morris
Law Foundation of Silicon Valley Public Interest Law Firm
152 N. Third Street, 3rd Floor
San Jose, CA 95112
(408) 280-2401

Anthony L. Francois
Pacific Legal Foundation
930 G Street
Sacramento, CA 95814
(916) 419-7111


3

Opinion Information
Date:Docket Number:
Mon, 06/15/2015S212072